COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and the Council on the issue of covered bonds and covered bond public supervision and amending Directive 2009/65/EC and Directive 2014/59/EU And Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and the Council on amending Regulation(EU) No 575/2013 as regards exposures in the form of covered bonds

Tilhører sager:

Aktører:


    1_EN_impact_assessment_part1_v3.pdf

    https://www.ft.dk/samling/20181/kommissionsforslag/KOM(2018)0094/kommissionsforslag/1482304/1883240.pdf

    EN EN
    EUROPEAN
    COMMISSION
    Brussels, 12.3.2018
    SWD(2018) 50 final
    COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
    IMPACT ASSESSMENT
    Accompanying the document
    Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and the Council on the issue of
    covered bonds and covered bond public supervision and amending Directive 2009/65/EC
    and Directive 2014/59/EU
    And
    Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and the Council on amending
    Regulation(EU) No 575/2013 as regards exposures in the form of covered bonds
    {COM(2018) 94 final} - {COM(2018) 93 final} - {SWD(2018) 51 final}
    Europaudvalget 2018
    KOM (2018) 0094
    Offentligt
    1
    1. INTRODUCTION
    One of the Commission's most important objectives is to stimulate investment and create jobs.
    To achieve that, the Commission has launched a number of initiatives to ensure that the
    financial system contributes fully in that regard. First among those is the Capital Markets
    Union (CMU), which contains a series of initiatives aimed at unlocking funding for Europe's
    growth. The key objective of CMU is to stimulate market financing. However, as bank
    financing is currently by far the most important funding channel in Europe, one of the actions
    of the CMU is to further leverage banking capacity to support the wider economy. One way to
    achieve that is to ensure that banks have a broad range of safe and efficient funding tools at
    their disposal.
    Covered bonds are important in that respect. Covered bonds are bonds issued by banks that
    are secured by earmarked assets on which investors have a priority claim. They are an
    important source of cheap and long-term funding for banks. They facilitate the financing of
    mortgage loans and public sector loans, thereby supporting lending more broadly.
    However, covered bonds are unevenly developed across the Single Market. They are very
    important in some Member States, less so in others. Furthermore, covered bonds are only
    partially addressed in EU law. Whereas covered bonds benefit from a preferential prudential
    and regulatory treatment in several respects in light of their lower risks – e.g. banks investing
    in covered bonds do not have to set aside as much regulatory capital as when they invest in
    other assets – what constitutes a covered bond is not comprehensively addressed in EU law.
    Instead, the various preferential treatments are granted to covered bonds as defined in the
    UCITS directive (2009/65/EC). That definition was, however, not drafted with this broader
    purpose in mind but had a more limited scope (limiting what UCITS could invest in).
    The desire to further leverage banking capacity, the uneven market development of covered
    bonds and their incomplete regulatory treatment at EU level has given rise to questions as to
    whether a review of the EU legislative framework is needed.
    The Commission carried out a public consultation on covered bonds between September 2015
    and January 2016, which already gave cautious support to EU wide harmonization. Since
    then, there has been a convergence of views on the merits of EU action. In December 2016,
    the EBA published recommendations on how to harmonise rules governing covered bonds. In
    March 2017, the Commission received a study commissioned from a third party (ICF)
    highlighting the benefits and costs of a possible legislative framework on covered bonds. The
    co-legislators have also expressed their support for addressing covered bonds. The European
    Parliament (EP) has called for the establishment of a European legislative framework on
    covered bonds.1
    Member States have also been supportive of further action subject to it being
    principle-based and in line with the EBA advice.2
    As a result, the Commission announced as part of the CMU Mid-term Review its intention to
    propose a legislative framework for covered bonds.3
    In his latest State of the Union speech,
    1
    European Parliament, (2017).
    2
    Financial Services Committee, 12 July 2017.
    3
    European Commission (2017a). The Mid-term Review also announced that the Commission will explore the
    possibility of developing European Secured Notes (ESNs) as an instrument using many of the key structural
    features of covered bonds, but aimed at SME bank loans and infrastructure bank loans. While the covered
    bond and ESN initiatives are closely linked, the case for ESNs is being assessed in parallel and according to
    a different timetable. As ESNs are backed by more risky assets, they will need further assessment and will
    2
    the President of the European Commission confirmed that an enabling framework for covered
    bonds was part of the initiatives to be launched or completed by end-2018.4
    The purpose of this impact assessment is therefore to assess the case for action (chapter 2), set
    the objectives that a new framework should aim to achieve (chapter 3) and to assess and
    compare different options for achieving those objectives (chapters 4-6).
    2. POLICY CONTEXT, PROBLEM DEFINITION AND SUBSIDIARITY
    2.1. Background and context
    What are covered bonds?
    Covered bonds are debt obligations issued by credit institutions and secured on the back of a
    ring-fenced pool of assets (the "cover pool" or "cover assets") which bondholders have direct
    recourse to as preferred creditors. Bondholders remain at the same time entitled to claim
    against the issuing entity or an affiliated entity of the issuer as ordinary creditors for any
    residual amounts not fully settled with the liquidation of the cover assets. This double claim
    against the cover pool and the issuer is denominated the "dual recourse" mechanism.
    Furthermore, the cover pool usually comprises high quality assets (e.g. mortgage loans and
    public sector debt). The issuer is under an obligation to ensure that the value of the assets in
    the cover pool at least matches at all times the value of the covered bonds and to replace
    assets that become non-performing, or otherwise do not meet the relevant eligibility criteria.
    These features reduce the risk of investments in covered bonds, thus providing a rationale for
    the beneficial regulatory capital requirements as set out in Article 129 CRR and for other
    favourable treatments envisaged in other pieces of EU legislation.
    Covered bonds are among the largest debt markets in the EU. They represent an important
    source of cheap and long-term funding for banks. They facilitate the refinancing of mortgage
    loans and public sector loans, thereby supporting lending more broadly. For investors they
    represent a safe investment, as in case of repayment problems they are covered by both the
    assets in the cover pool and by the issuer (dual recourse). The lower risk profile of the asset
    pool and the dual recourse mechanism reduce the required rate of return for investors and
    enable mortgage banks to raise finance more cheaply than by just issuing unsecured bonds.
    This should normally increase the supply of funding available to the economy, in particular
    mortgages. Although residential mortgages finance predominantly real estate, entrepreneurs
    can also use their residential property as collateral for financing their professional activity;
    commercial mortgages finance business facilities (offices, productive capacity and shopping
    malls, etc); public sector loans finance local infrastructure (like schools, hospitals etc) and
    possibly guarantee SME loans; finally, covered bonds in some cases also refinance other
    assets such as SME loans and infrastructure loans. Covered bonds have therefore wider
    financing benefits beyond banks and are important to fulfil broader CMU objectives.
    Moreover, covered bonds proved to be a stable source of funding for banks during the
    financial crisis compared to the more volatile senior unsecured debt issued by banks.
    have a separate impact assessment process to assess the merits of legislative action. In light of the above, the
    SME issue is not within the scope of the present impact assessment.
    4
    European Commission, (2017b).
    3
    The EBA mandates and Reports
    On 1 July 2014, the EBA issued a ‘Report on EU covered bond frameworks and capital
    treatment’ (2014 EBA report)5
    which, in line with the mandate given to the EBA in the ESRB
    recommendation on the funding of credit institutions from December 2012 (ESRB
    recommendation6
    ), identified best practices with a view to ensuring robust and consistent
    frameworks for covered bonds across the EU. The report also contained the EBA’s opinion on
    the adequacy of the current prudential treatment of covered bonds, following a call for advice
    from the Commission from December 2013 based on the Article 503 of the CRR.
    As a follow-up to the identification of best practices, the ESRB recommended to the EBA to
    monitor the functioning of the market for covered bonds by reference to these best practices
    for a period of 2 years. By 2016, the EBA was requested to deliver a final report to the ESRB
    and to the Council and the Commission containing an assessment of the functioning of the
    market for covered bonds under the best practice principles and its view on recommended
    further action if deemed desirable.
    In response to this recommendation, in December 2016 the EBA issued a "Report on covered
    bonds - Recommendations on harmonisation of covered bond frameworks in the EU".7
    The
    report was the subject of a public hearing on November 2016. This Report includes a
    comprehensive analysis of regulatory developments in covered bond frameworks in
    individual Member States, with a particular focus on the level of alignment with the EBA’s
    best practices. It also provides an assessment of the latest market trends, as well as regulatory
    developments that have taken place at the European level. Building on the results of the
    analysis, the report advocates for EU legislative action for harmonizing covered bonds at EU
    level and presents a comprehensive proposal to this purpose.
    The EP Report
    On 4th
    July 2017, the European Parliament approved an own-initiative report on covered
    bonds titled "Towards a pan-European covered bonds framework"8
    . The Report has been
    presented before the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs (ECON) and the Plenary
    by the Rapporteur Bernd LUCKE (ECR/DE). The report supports the harmonisation of
    covered bonds at EU level, calling the Commission to present a principles-based Directive for
    a European Covered Bonds framework. The report recognizes that covered bonds are sound
    financial products and that some national frameworks are already very successful. It also
    raises the concern that a fully-fledged harmonisation aiming at a one-size-fits-all European
    model would have negative consequences. It therefore proposes a principle-based approach
    based on high quality standards and best practices but leaving means and ways to Member
    States to adapt the EU framework to their national specificities.
    The ICF study
    In 2016 the Commission launched a tender for a study on covered bonds to assess their
    current market performance and the costs and benefits of potential EU action. The study has
    5
    EBA (2014).
    6
    ESRB (2012).
    7
    EBA (2016).
    8
    European Parliament Report (2017).
    4
    been awarded to the consultancy ICF, which delivered their final report in March 20179
    . The
    Commission published it in May 2017. On the basis of a literature review; qualitative and
    quantitative analysis and stakeholder interviews (issuers, investors, supervisors…), the study
    documents a number of costs and benefits of EU action. In terms of costs, these relate to: i)
    costs for issuers to establish new covered bond programmes; ii) transition costs; and iii) risks
    of undermining well-functioning national markets. As regards benefits, one key benefit of the
    new EU framework would be a reduction of the overall default probability of covered bonds
    due to the strengthening of the credit characteristics of the instrument. This credit
    strengthening would translate into materially lower borrowing costs for EU credit institutions
    issuing covered bonds of several basis points. The study also highlights other benefits (e.g.
    reducing regulatory fragmentation; facilitating reduction of asset and liability mismatches;
    and, facilitating capital market access to small and medium-sized issuers), though it does not
    quantify them. Overall, the study finds that benefits exceed costs and therefore EU action is
    justified.
    The European Secured Note (ESN) initiative
    The European Secured Note (ESN) is defined as a dual-recourse financial instrument on an
    issuer's balance sheet applying the basic structural characteristics of covered bonds to two
    non-traditional cover pool assets - SME bank loans and infrastructure bank loans. The
    Communication on the Mid-term Review of the Capital Markets Union (CMU) Action Plan of
    June 2017 announced that along with an EU framework on covered bonds, the Commission
    will assess the case for ESNs in order to strengthen the banking sector's lending capacity and
    support the wider economy. While the covered bond and ESN initiatives are closely linked (as
    the ESNs make use of most structural features of covered bonds and transfer the covered bond
    technology to non-mortgage cover pools), it has been decided to follow a separate parallel
    path for ESN in order to protect the strong reputation covered bonds earned in the last decades
    in European financial markets. As ESNs are backed by more risky assets, they would
    inevitably represent a riskier instrument and their perceived higher risk could affect the
    perception of traditional covered bonds. Member States, supervisors and market stakeholders
    all have expressed their reserves against connecting the two instruments. The opportunity of
    an EU initiative on ESN will therefore be subject to a separate impact assessment. This
    approach is shared by the co-legislators. Following the ECOFIN Council Conclusions of 11
    July10
    , Member States discussed ESNs at the Financial Services Committee meeting on 12
    July based on a non-paper prepared by the Commission. Member States were overall
    supportive of the ESN initiative subject to clear differentiation of ESNs from covered bonds
    and further analysis. In its report on a pan-European covered bonds framework issued in
    July11
    , the European Parliament (EP) has expressed support for the establishment of ESNs and
    called on the Commission to develop principles of a legal framework for ESNs.
    In order to prepare a specific impact assessment12
    , the ESN work stream will build on the
    EBA advice (to be delivered by 30 April 2018), on a feasibility study by an external
    contractor (to be delivered on 30 April 2018) and on data collected with the help of the ECBC
    9
    ICF (2017).
    10
    Council conclusions on the Commission Communication on the mid-term review of the Capital Markets
    Union Action Plan, 11.07.2017
    11
    European parliament, Towards a pan-European covered bonds framework, (2017/2005(INI)), 26.06.2017
    12
    Issues that need to be evaluated are the following: the potential demand for ESNs, default rates of SME and
    infrastructure bank loans, cover pool quality and eligibility criteria, geographical diversification of the cover
    pool, interest of international investors, liquidity risk profile, data infrastructure, system of supervision and
    administration, potential non-traditional amortisation structures and effect on markets for other asset classes.
    5
    Task Force on ESNs. The Commission will also launch an open public consultation on ESNs
    by the end of 2017.
    2.1.1. Nature and size of the market concerned
    As outlined above, covered bonds are an important funding tool that has been subject to
    significant policy attention recently. This section further describes covered bond markets in
    terms of the size of the market; who issues and invests in covered bonds; and, the type of
    assets used as collateral. This section also compares covered bond issuance with another
    funding tool of banks, i.e. securitisation.
    Outstanding volumes
    According to information compiled by ICF13
    , as of December 2015, the outstanding volume
    of covered bonds reached EUR2.5 trillion at the global level, of which EUR2.1 trillion has
    been issued by EU resident institutions. To put it into perspective, this figure amounts to
    about 1.2 times the outstanding volume of corporate bonds issued by non-financial institutions
    in the EU (which stood at EUR1.8 trillion in 2015) and 4.8 per cent of the aggregate balance
    sheet of EU banks (EUR43.3 trillion in 2015).
    Covered bonds are predominantly an EU instrument. The EU represents 84 per cent of the
    global outstanding volumes, followed by 11 per cent of non-EEA countries and 5 per cent of
    non-EU EEA countries. Although still comparatively small in absolute terms, the non-EEA
    markets have recently been growing rapidly: between 2003 and 2015, non-EEA markets
    posted a compound annual growth rate of 20 per cent compared to 3 per cent for the EU. One
    of the reasons why the EU has a comparatively large market for covered bonds is the fact that
    many Member States have longstanding enabling legal framework for covered bonds in place.
    Figure 1. Evolution of Total Outstanding Covered Bonds [2003-2015, in EUR billion]
    Source: ICF, 2017
    As shown in Figure 1, the global covered bond market has grown steadily for more than 20
    years, in particular since 1995. From roughly 2003 until the financial crisis, the twin drivers
    of overall market growth were the introduction of covered bond regimes in many new
    13
    Data in this section come from ICF (2017).
    6
    jurisdictions and the tightening spread environment. During the financial crisis the issuance
    level was relatively high as issuers relied more heavily on covered bond funding than on
    unsecured bonds. Some of the increase in market size from 2007 to its peak in 2012 can be
    attributed to issuers switching their funding sources from unsecured to secured funding. The
    other main driver of higher reported levels of covered bonds outstanding in the same period
    was the increase in bonds issued purely for use as collateral to access the funding made
    available by the ECB14
    . Since 2012, the global market size has shrunk slightly: outstanding
    bonds contracted by 7 per cent in 2013 before declining more slowly to €2.5 trillion in 2015.
    This global decrease was driven by a decline in EU covered bonds, with the rest of the world
    still experiencing a slow but steady increase in the size of covered bond markets. Anecdotally,
    the main reasons for the decline in the EU covered bond market have been a normalisation of
    the spread differential between covered and unsecured bank bonds, less use of central bank
    emergency funding facilities (therefore less need for covered bonds as collateral), low levels
    of growth in bank lending in general, and mortgage lending in particular, and regulatory
    developments including the need for banks to raise more funding in the form of capital (and
    other bail-in eligible liabilities).
    As shown in figure 2, within the EU, Germany remains the largest market in terms of
    outstanding volume (384 bn EUR), closely followed by Denmark (383 bn EUR), France (323
    bn EUR), Spain (281 bn EUR), Sweden (222 bn EUR), Italy (131 bn EUR) and the UK (121
    bn EUR). The four largest markets still account for almost two-thirds of the EU market in
    2015 (vs. 97 per cent in 2003).
    Figure 2. Size of the seven largest markets in terms of outstanding volumes (2015)
    Source: ICF, 2017
    Issuance
    As of 2015, there were 317 active covered bond issuers15
    globally (261 in the EU) and 434
    covered bond programmes, in 30 countries. Within the EU, there has been an increase in the
    number of issuers from 139 in 2003 to 261 in 2015. Germany is still the top EU country in
    terms of the number of credit institutions issuing covered bonds (79). Spain has 31 active
    issuers, followed by Austria (27), France (19), the UK (15) and Italy (13). There are also
    substantial differences between the countries in terms of the typical size of the issuer.
    14
    Within the Eurosystem Collateral Data, covered bonds make up 19 per cent of assets used as collateral.
    15
    Issuers of covered bonds can only be credit institutions.
    7
    Up until 2012, the annual level of issuance in the EU increased substantially, rising from €394
    billion in 2003 to €613 billion in 2011. This upward trend halted temporarily in 2012 and
    2013 (-2 per cent and -39 per cent respectively). The market quickly recovered – with year-
    on-year growth rates standing at +4 per cent and +20 per cent in 2014 and 2015 respectively –
    to reach a level of €454 billion.
    Denmark is the country with the largest new gross issuance volumes in 2015 (EUR164bn).
    Other major issuers are Sweden (EUR61bn), Germany (EUR58bn), France (EUR45bn), Spain
    (EUR42bn) and Italy (EUR29bn).
    Non-EEA issuers are catching up and their share increased from 1 per cent in 2003 to 11 per
    cent in 2015. The number of countries outside the EEA with active covered bond markets has
    grown: Singapore is the latest 2015 addition to a list already containing Australia, Canada,
    New Zealand, Switzerland, South Korea and Turkey. The US is not active in the market of
    covered bonds due to the different structure of their mortgage market which is dominated by
    the two public agencies Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
    Composition of the cover pool
    In terms of outstanding volumes, the two traditional asset classes still dominate the EU
    market: mortgages represented 80 per cent of the cover pool in outstanding covered bonds in
    2015 and public sector debt 16 per cent, the rest accounting for other assets such as ships.
    Figure 3. Composition of the cover pool in EU countries’ outstanding covered bonds [2003-2015],
    figures in bars are in € billion
    Source: ICF, 2017
    As shown in figure 3, the composition of the cover pool in the EU is gradually shifting away
    from public sector debt towards mortgage debt. Public sector debt represented 59 per cent of
    total assets in 2003 and fell to 16 per cent in 2015, while mortgages increased from 38 per
    cent in 2003 to 80 per cent in 2015. This trend is confirmed by the composition of the cover
    pool of new issuances.
    8
    Investor base
    Banks and central banks are the most important investors in covered bonds, accounting for
    almost two-thirds of the markets (32 per cent and 31 per cent each in 2016), as shown in
    Figure 4. Asset managers’, insurance companies’ and pension funds’ investment in this
    market account for the remaining third (about 36 per cent in 2016). Retail investors do not
    play a significant role in this market (they are included in the category others which itself
    represents only 1%). This is mainly explained by the fact that in most cases the minimum
    denomination of covered bonds is 100.000 EUR. The two countries with the largest covered
    bond markets (Germany and Denmark) allow retail investors to directly invest in covered
    bonds. While in Denmark, in spite of this possibility, retail investors do not invest in covered
    bonds, in Germany saving banks sell covered bonds to their customers in the secondary
    market only (there are no retail investors in primary markets). However, the share of retail
    investors in secondary markets is quite modest, slightly higher than 1%, but in any case not
    exceeding 10%.16
    Based on the above, the covered bond market does not look suited to retail
    investors. Therefore, the possible role of covered bonds as potential retail investment products
    and the related possible adaptations of the disclosure requirements are not assessed in this
    impact assessment. Whilst retail investors play no significant direct role, they are nevertheless
    important players by (indirectly) providing funds to insurance / asset managers that then
    invest in covered bonds on their behalf.
    Figure 4. Investor distribution by investor group (by year)
    Source: ICF, 2017
    Two factors dominate recent trends in the investor distribution of covered bonds:
     Firstly, negative or very low absolute yields have reduced the purchases of covered bonds
    by asset managers, pension funds and insurance companies. Their shares among investors
    declined from 44 per cent in 2010 to 36 per cent in 2016.
    16
    No reliable figures exist on the share of retail investors in German covered bond secondary markets.
    Estimates reported in the text come from VDP (Association of German Pfandbrief Banks).
    9
     Secondly, central banks have significantly increased their investments in covered bonds
    over the past years (12 per cent in 2010 to 31 per cent in 2016) – as a consequence of the
    successive Covered Bond Purchase Programmes (see next section).
    ECB purchasing programme
    Covered bonds are an important instrument in the conduct of monetary policy in the euro
    area. The Eurosystem has taken a number of extraordinary measures in support of covered
    bond markets during the financial crisis, becoming the larger buyer of covered bonds in the
    EU (nearly a third of the market).
    CBPPs are successive interventions of the Eurosystem and represent key elements of the
    ECB's asset purchase programmes, initially aimed at restoring liquidity in the inter-banking
    market and facilitating the monetary policy transmission, and recently being part of the
    quantitative easing policy. Concretely, the Eurosystem purchases covered bonds, both in
    primary and secondary markets. The first two CBPPs, both one-year programmes, were
    implemented in 2009/10 and 2011/12 respectively. The third, CBPP3, began in October 2014
    and is ongoing. By the end of 2016, CBPP3 holdings stood at €203 billion, 70 per cent of
    which was on secondary markets. Recent data suggest that by early 2017, the Eurosystem has
    already bought €210 billion of bonds under its third programme. CBPP3 substantially
    impacted the composition of covered bonds’ investor base – with the share of central banks
    reaching 31 per cent in 2015/16 (up from 16 per cent in 2014 and 8 per cent in 2013). CBPP3
    has also impacted supply and translated into an expansion of the covered bond issuer base.
    Covered bonds and the real estate market
    The importance of covered bonds for the real estate market is exemplified by the following
    numbers (ECBC data). Covered bonds cover an average of 30% of residential mortgages
    lending in the EU in 2015. There is a high degree of variability across countries. In Denmark
    all residential mortgages are financed through covered bonds. In other Northern countries
    (Sweden and Finland) the percentage is also quite high (between 37 and 60%). Slightly lower,
    but still above one third is the share in Mediterranean countries (Spain, Italy, Portugal). The
    percentage is 23% in France and 16% in Germany.
    There is a close relationship between the level of development of covered bond markets and
    the interest rates on mortgages. The country with the lowest interest spreads on mortgages is
    Denmark with an average short-term interest rate spread of 1.28% in 2015. Denmark is also
    the country in the EU with one of the best developed covered bond markets and with the
    highest proportion of covered bonds in terms of banking assets (37.4%, see table 2).17
    Figure
    5 shows that an inverse relationship between short-term interest rate spreads on mortgages
    and development of covered bond markets exists for all EU countries with available EMF
    data (a similar, slightly less negative relationship can be seen on long-term rates)18
    .
    17
    This is also recognized by the Commission Country Report on Denmark (2017) which explicitly states that
    the unique Danish mortgage system has been able to provide households with a large number of low-cost
    mortgage loans, resulting in one of the lowest mortgage rates in the EU (p. 17).
    18
    The inverse relationship holds also eliminating outliers DK and SE. In that case, the correlation coefficient
    (R-squared) decreases from 0.24 to 0.18.
    10
    Figure 5. Relationship between short-term mortgage spreads and level of development of covered
    bond markets (outstanding covered bonds as a share of bank assets), 2016.
    Sources: EMF, ECBC, ECB, Eurostat
    This negative correlation between covered bond market development and mortgage spreads
    does of course not imply a causal relationship as there are a large range of other factors that
    influence spreads in different countries that cannot easily be controlled for. However, a high
    level of development of covered bond markets and a lower cost of funding for banks can be
    considered conducive to expand the availability of credit to the real economy and to lower
    lending rates. There is a relative consensus in the economic literature that bank's funding costs
    gradually pass through to lending rates. More specifically, research suggests that policy and
    market interest rates get to a large extent reflected in retail lending rates over a longer term
    horizon, while the short-term adjustment may be sluggish (see a review in De Bondt, 2002). A
    breakdown in the relationship between policy rates and lending rates has been observed in the
    aftermath of the global financial crisis in some euro area countries (Darracq-Paries et al,
    2014). However, Illes et al. (2015) show that the pass-through has been comparably high in
    the pre- and post-crisis periods, once we account for banks' actual funding costs.
    Covered bonds vs securitization
    Another source of funding for banks which has similar features to covered bonds is
    securitization. The Commission's objective is to provide the widest possible panoply of safe
    and efficient funding instruments for the banking sector to support banks' lending to the real
    economy.
    In spite of their similarities, covered bonds and securitization feature different characteristics
    which make them suitable for different purposes and strategies both for issuers and for
    investors. The main difference between the two is the dual recourse mechanism: in
    securitization the holder of the securitized product does not hold any claim towards the issuer.
    The originate-to-distribute model which mainly underpins securitization can be tempered in
    order to ensure the issuer keeps some "skin in the game"19
    . By contrast, by keeping a full
    enforcing claim towards the issuer, covered bonds ensure full "skin in the game" by design.
    That is one of the reasons why historically EU legislators have been ready to grant a
    19
    See for example G. Chemla and C. Hennesy (2014), pp. 1597–1641.
    11
    significant preferential prudential treatment to covered bonds (see next section) which is not
    matched by the treatment granted to securitization. Thus the same underlying assets enjoy a
    better prudential treatment if they are used as collateral in the cover pool of a covered bond
    than if they are securitized. This means holding covered bonds is more convenient for
    investors in terms of capital requirements (especially for banks) than holding securitized
    products.
    The special treatment covered bonds enjoy appears justified if one considers how differently
    the two products fared during the financial crisis. Whereas covered bonds proved to be a less
    pro-cyclical product during that period of stress, as they offered a long-term and stable
    funding source for banks at a moment when funding channels were drying up, securitization
    fared differently. Though securitization in the EU did not fare as badly as in the US, it still
    suffered the stigma of the crisis which led to the collapse of the market. To respond to this
    market failure, the Commission proposed rules for a simple and transparent securitization.
    This is another important difference between the two instruments: while the market for
    securitization was broken after the crisis and needed to be fixed, in the case of covered bonds
    the market continued to work well. The rationales underpinning action in these two areas are
    therefore of a different nature.
    Overall, the two products both present advantages and disadvantages. It is up to banks and
    investors to assess them and choose the more appropriate funding/investing tool for them at a
    specific point in time based on their balance sheet and risk/liquidity requirements. The
    objective of the Commission is to ensure that banks have a wide range of safe and efficient
    funding tools at their disposal. This is why it proposed legislation on simple, transparent and
    standardised securitisations and is the reason why it is assessing the case for action as regards
    covered bonds.
    2.1.2. Overview of legislative framework
    Covered bonds are mainly regulated at national level. Most Member States have working
    covered bond markets in place.20
    Others either do not have covered bond frameworks in place,
    or their frameworks are outdated, the effect being that there is virtually no active covered
    bond market in those Member States.21
    The national regimes in place are different, e.g. in terms of public supervision, disclosure,
    composition of the cover pool22
    . The different national covered bond regimes impact on the
    credit strength of the instrument and, therefore, on the degree to which instruments issued
    under different jurisdictions are eligible for EU wide preferential treatment.
    There is currently no EU-wide dedicated legislative framework for covered bonds. There is,
    however, a body of EU law that regulates the prudential treatment for investments in covered
    bonds (Figure 6).
    20
    AT, BE, CZ, DK, FI, FR, DE, EL, ES, HU, IE, IT, LU, NL, PL, PT, SE and UK.
    21
    Examples of Member States without a framework include Croatia, Estonia and Malta. Examples of outdated
    frameworks include Bulgaria, Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania, Slovenia. In Slovakia, covered bond legislation has
    been recently amended following the lines of the EBA best practices and is set to come into effect in January
    2018. In Romania the legal framework has just been amended.
    22
    For an overview of the differences in national regimes see EBA (2016) and ICF (2017) p. 16
    12
    Figure 6. EU rules regulating covered bonds
    Source: Commission services, 2017
    The treatment of covered bonds under EU law differs from the Basel rules (or other
    international standards, for example IOSCO), which do not grant specific preferential
    treatment to covered bonds.
    The remainder of this section outlines the different aspects of preferential treatment in further
    detail.
    Higher investment limits for UCITS
    Under the UCITS Directive23
    , a “UCITS” (i.e. certain investment funds) cannot invest more
    than 5 per cent of its assets in transferable securities issued by the same entity. Article 52(4)
    of the UCITS Directive, however, allows Member States to raise this investment limit to 25
    per cent for investments in “UCITS compliant covered bonds” issued by a single entity.
    Article 52(4) specifies the following minimum requirements for covered bonds as the basis
    for easing of prudential investment limits:
     The covered bond issuer must be a credit institution with a registered office in an EU
    Member State;
     The issuer should be subject, by law, to special public supervision designed to protect
    bond-holders;
     The cover asset pool must provide sufficient collateral to cover bondholder claims
    throughout the whole term of the covered bond; and
     Bondholders must have priority claim on the cover asset pool in case of default of the
    issuer.
    Article 52(4) also obliges Member States to send the Commission a list of covered bonds that
    comply with the above criteria together with the categories of issuers authorised to issue such
    23
    Directive 2009/65/EC on Undertakings for Collective Investment in Transferable Securities (UCITS).
    13
    bonds. Article 52(4) accordingly de facto defines a covered bond for EU regulatory purposes,
    serving as a reference for several other pieces of EU legislation.
    Lower capital requirements for banks investing in covered bonds
    According to the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR)24
    , credit institutions must hold
    regulatory capital in respect of debt securities held on their books, risk-weighted according to
    the type of issuer and obligation. However, article 129 CRR allow those investing in covered
    to hold lower levels of regulatory capital in relation to these instruments as compared to other
    debt such as senior unsecured bank debt.25
    These lower capital requirements are referred to by
    the CRR as "preferential risk weights". These preferential risk weights are, however, only
    available for "qualifying covered bonds”. To qualify for preferential treatment, covered bonds
    must be (a) UCITS compliant [Art. 129 (1) CRR]; (b) secured by specific cover assets [Art.
    129 (1) CRR]; and (c) satisfy various transparency requirements [Art. 129 (7) CRR].
    Art 129 is addressed to bank investors who use the standard approach to capital risk weight
    allocation. While the internal ratings based approaches are substantially more complex they
    also allow similar levels of preferential risk weighting treatment.
    Special treatment in recovery and resolution
    Article 44(2) of the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive (BRRD) 26
    exempts UCITS-
    compliant covered bonds from the scope of the bail-in tool. It should be highlighted, however,
    that the BRRD limits this exemption up to the level of collateral in the cover pool.
    Apart from bail-in, the application of other resolution tools might also have implications for
    covered bonds, particularly in the context of partial transfer of assets/liabilities to bridge
    institution or asset management vehicles. The BRRD also provides for safeguards to be
    applied in the case of partial transfers (Article 76), and Article 79 requests Members States to
    ensure— in the event of the partial transfers—appropriate protection of covered bonds and to
    prevent the assets, rights and liabilities from being separated under a partial transfer, or being
    terminated or modified through the use of ancillary powers.
    Lower solvency capital requirements for insurance undertakings investing in covered bonds
    Article 180(1) of the Solvency II Delegated Regulation lays down the capital requirements for
    (re)insurance undertakings investing in covered bonds.27
    The term 'covered bond' is not
    defined within the Solvency II Delegated Regulation itself. The definition is derived from the
    UCITS Directive Article 52(4). The Delegated Regulation contains certain risk calibrations in
    its standard formula which is used by many insurers28
    to compute their solvency capital
    requirement. The Delegated Regulation contains a preferential treatment for covered bonds in
    comparison with similar rated corporate bonds. The risk calibrations for covered bonds are in
    24
    Capital Requirement Regulation (EU) No 575/2013 (CRR).
    25
    E.g. 10 per cent risk weight for a "credit quality step 1" covered bond compared to 20 per cent for another type
    of direct exposure to a credit institution of the same step.
    26
    Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive No 59/2014 (BRRD)
    27
    Commission's Delegated Regulation (EU) 2015/35 (Solvency II Delegated Act)
    28
    Some insurers who have received an approval to their internal models do not use the risk calibrations in the
    standard formula. These are typically large insurance companies.
    14
    between those applicable to corporate bonds and government bonds, provided the covered
    bonds are highly rated.
    Favourable treatment in banks' liquidity requirements
    The LCR Delegated Act requires that banks hold enough high quality liquid assets to cover
    the difference between the expected outflows and inflows over a 30-day stressed period.29
    It
    provides favourable treatment to covered bonds by allowing credit institutions to hold covered
    bonds as part of their liquidity requirements i.e. it allows credit institutions to treat covered
    bonds as liquid assets of level 1, if they qualify as "extremely high quality", or as level 2, if
    they are so called "high quality", for the purposes of calculating their liquidity coverage ratio
    (LCR). The LCR Delegated Act sets out a number of specific criteria to differentiate between
    covered bonds of level 1 and 2 and also incorporates by reference the well-established
    covered bond definition contained in Article 52(4) of the UCITS Directive.
    Specific treatment of cover pool derivatives as regards clearing
    Under the EMIR, derivatives should normally be cleared through a central clearing
    counterparty. As covered bond derivatives contain certain non-standard clauses they are
    typically not eligible for CCP clearing. The Regulatory and Implementing Technical
    Standards (RTS) under this regulation for risk mitigation for derivatives that are not cleared
    provide for a specific treatment of cover pool derivatives.30
    Under a specific set of conditions,
    covered bonds issuers or cover pools should not be required to post collateral for the
    derivatives held to hedge risks inherent to the cover pool. To obtain this treatment, the
    derivatives must meet certain conditions including compliance of the covered bonds to whose
    cover pool they belong to with Article 129 of the CRR and with a minimum level of
    overcollateralization of 2%.
    2.2. Problem definition
    Covered bonds are an important funding tool for banks. Their markets are well-developed in
    some Member States and less so in others. Given their particular risk features, they also
    benefit from a preferential prudential treatment in several respects. This treatment rests on a
    definition of covered bonds set out in UCITS, which originally was developed with a more
    limited purpose in mind. Taken together, this gives rise to two sets of concerns.
    The first is related to the untapped CMU potential. Covered bond markets are currently
    fragmented along national borders, and national regulatory frameworks differ significantly.
    This creates legal uncertainty and gives rise to the following problems:
    (1) covered bond markets are unevenly developed across the EU: not all banks from
    different countries and of different size are able to exploit the cheap and stable source
    of funding that covered bonds represent;
    (2) the investor basis is not sufficiently diversified;
    (3) there is untapped potential for cross border investments;
    (4) investments from outside the EU are low.
    29
    Commission's Delegated Regulation (EU) 2015/61 with regard to liquidity coverage requirement for Credit
    Institutions (LCR).
    30
    Commission Delegated Regulation 2016/2251 supplementing European Market Infrastructure Regulation
    (“EMIR”) No 648/2012
    15
    The second regards prudential concerns and related risks to e.g. investor protection. The
    main problems in this area are the following:
    (1) misalignment between the fact that EU law does not directly lay down the structural
    characteristics of the product, which mostly derive from national law, and the
    favourable treatment granted to investments in covered bonds at EU level;
    (2) inadequate current capital preferential treatment envisaged in art 129 CRR;
    (3) ongoing financial innovation which could pose threats in terms of investor protection.
    2.2.1. Untapped CMU potential
    This section outlines how markets are unevenly developed in terms of issuance, the limited
    range of investors, and the limited range of cross-border investments both within the Single
    Market and beyond.
    Unevenly developed markets
    Covered bonds are unevenly developed across the EU as shown in tables 1 and 2. Covered
    bond issuance is dominated by a few Member States. Approximately 80% of global covered
    bond issuance is represented by six Member States (Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, Spain
    and Sweden). The four largest outstanding markets (Germany, Denmark, France, and Spain)
    accounted for almost two-thirds of the EU market in 2015. At the same time, nine Member
    States do not have any covered bond markets.
    Table 1 – Uneven development of covered bond markets
    Member State Legal framework Compliance with
    EBA Best Practices
    Active market Size of the market
    (relative to total
    EU market)
    AT  Low  Medium
    BE  Medium  Medium
    BG  NA  NA
    HR  NA  NA
    CY  Medium  Small
    CZ  Low  Medium
    DE  Medium  Large
    DK  High  Large
    EE  NA  NA
    EL  High  Small
    ES  Medium  Large
    FI  High  Medium
    FR  High  Large
    HU  NA  Small
    IE  Medium  Medium
    IT  Medium  Large
    LT  NA  NA
    LV  NA  NA
    LU  Low  Small
    MT  NA  NA
    NL  High  Medium
    16
    PL  Medium  Small
    PT  Medium  Medium
    RO  High*  NA
    SK  Low  Small
    SI  Medium  NA
    SE  Medium  Large
    UK  High  Large
    Source: Commission Services elaborations based on EBA (2016) and ECBC Fact Book (2016).
    Legend: Small < €10 bn, Medium < €100 bn, Large > €100 bn.
    *After recent amendments, Romanian framework can be considered highly compliant with EBA best practices.
    The uneven development of covered bond markets is also apparent if one compares the size of
    national covered bond markets with the size of national banking sectors (see table 2). In 19
    out of 28 Member States this ratio is below 4.4% (the EU average), while in three the ratio is
    at or above 10% (Denmark, Sweden and Spain).31
    Table 2 – Ratio of outstanding covered bonds / banking assets (2015)
    EU country Ratio CB/ bank
    assets
    Total CB outstanding
    (EUR mln, 2015)
    Total banking assets
    (EUR mln, 2015)
    Denmark 37,4% 383.124 1.024.778
    Sweden 17,3% 221.990 1.281.511
    Spain 9,9% 280.888 2.828.440
    Portugal 7,8% 34.961 450.063
    Finland 6,1% 33.974 556.050
    Slovakia 6,1% 4.198 69.104
    Czech Republic 5,6% 11.656 206.630
    Austria 5,3% 44.965 854.229
    Germany 5,0% 384.414 7.665.206
    France 4,0% 323.072 8.150.044
    Italy 3,3% 130.535 3.919.502
    Ireland 3,0% 32.305 1.086.843
    Hungary 2,7% 3.022 112.408
    Netherlands 2,5% 61.101 2.430.643
    Belgium 1,6% 16.905 1.073.501
    United Kingdom 1,3% 121.268 9.355.722
    Greece 1,3% 4.961 386.025
    Luxembourg 1,0% 10.166 1.002.760
    Cyprus 0,7% 650 91.020
    Poland 0,3% 1.266 394.333
    Bulgaria 0,0% 0 48.585
    Estonia 0,0% 0 23.240
    Croatia 0,0% 0 57.879
    Latvia 0,0% 0 31.932
    Lithuania 0,0% 0 24.783
    31
    Among the countries where the ratio is significantly below EU average or the market is not developed at all,
    there are MS with different banking structures: we find both countries where typically the banking sector is
    foreign-owned and countries where there is a strong domestic banking sector. This would suggest that the
    uneven development of covered bond markets is not related to the ownership structure of the banking sector.
    17
    Malta 0,0% 0 47.397
    Romania 0,0% 0 92.288
    Slovenia 0,0% 0 41.603
    EU 4,4% 2.105.421 43.306.519
    Source: Commission Services estimates.
    Another way to look at the uneven development of covered bond markets in relative terms is
    to consider the ratio between covered bonds outstanding and residential mortgages in different
    countries. While the EU average is 30%, there is a lot of variability across countries with
    Denmark at 100% and Poland at 1.4%.
    The reasons why covered bonds developed in some Member States and not in others is partly
    due to history. The instrument was created decades ago (in some cases even centuries ago, as
    in Denmark and Germany it is around 200 years old) and has grown gradually over time.
    There are several factors which underpin the development of covered bond markets. Some of
    them are of a macroeconomic32
    and structural nature33
    . There are, however, important
    regulatory factors that play a crucial role in the development of covered bond markets. They
    include:
    i. the existence of an enabling regulatory framework that commands confidence among
    investors; and
    ii. broader regulatory elements related to the insolvency framework and the
    enforceability of collateral, including foreclosure processes and legal aspects of asset
    transfer.
    The lack of a legal framework in Member States characterised by underdeveloped covered
    bond markets in principle confirm the importance of regulatory factors. However, the cases of
    countries with legal frameworks in place, but no active covered bonds market (see table 1)
    could also suggest that other factors play a significant role. As outlined above, a legislative
    framework for covered bond is indeed in place in six of the nine Member States that do not
    have covered bond markets. As also outlined, the framework is in most instances outdated and
    not able to support a properly functioning market.34
    Some economic factors might help
    explain the lack of urgency in dealing with regulation. For example, countries with non-
    existent or very small covered bond markets are usually characterized by a lack of
    diversification in banks' funding sources. In many Central and Eastern European countries,
    banks mainly rely on deposits for their funding35
    . The abundance and availability of bank
    deposits makes the need to find alternative funding sources less compelling.
    However, there are several reasons why this situation is not sustainable in the longer term.
    First, banks with a broad and diversified range of funding tools are more resilient, as
    recognised by the IMF (2013) and the BIS (2013)36
    . In times of crisis, covered bonds allow
    banks to continue access funding markets, as was evident during the financial crisis,
    32
    In particular, factors predicting demand for residential housing, including level of per capita GDP,
    unemployment, inflation and credit demand.
    33
    Factors related to the level of development of financial markets, in particular of bond markets, and to the
    level of development of the banking sector, in particular the degree to which funding is needed outside the
    deposit-based system and the demand of funding by end-users to purchase properties.
    34
    BG, CY, LT, LV, SI. Romania has just finalised a new legal framework.
    35
    In BU, HR, EE, LT, LV, RO, SI, mortgages are 100% financed through deposits. In HU, PL and SK,
    covered bonds finance only a small portion of mortgages (in PL this is less than 1%).
    36
    Van Rixtel and Gasperini, 2013 (BIS Working Paper 406).
    18
    especially in some peripheral European countries. For many banks most notably from Spain,
    Italy, Greece, Ireland and Portugal, this instrument became the main source of long-term
    wholesale funding, as their access to unsecured markets was partially or fully closed (Van
    Rixtel and Gasperini, 2013). Secondly, in normal times, in order to finance growth in banks'
    balance sheets, banks need other sources of funding than deposits. Deposits indeed can grow
    only up to a certain limit and, at the same time, they need to be financed through more capital,
    while covered bonds have lower capital and liquidity requirements. Finally, from the
    investing bank's point of view, covered bonds can be used as liquid assets to meet liquidity
    requirements (for example in the LCR).
    Nevertheless, covered bonds also present some risks. One of the main risks resulting from a
    significant growth in covered bond markets is asset encumbrance i.e. assets specifically
    pledged to pay for certain liabilities. However, according to the EBA (2017), the level of asset
    encumbrance in Member States where covered bond markets do not exist or are
    underdeveloped is low at the moment (ranging between 0% and 10%)37
    .
    Undertaking a process of updating the existing legislation requires, however, specific
    expertise and collaboration between different institutional actors including the ministry of
    finance and the supervisors. This, along with the non-urgency of the bank funding
    diversification in some Member States, explains why some of them did not embark in the
    process. Other Member States are doing it with the help of the EBRD (EE, HR, LT, LV, PL,
    RO, SK)38
    . In Poland, for example, where the ratio of deposit to loans was 94% at the end of
    201639
    , the planned total asset growth for 2017 is 15% (EBA, 2017) and the planned deposit
    growth 18%. However, planned deposit growth rates are not always met40
    and even a small
    negative deviation from the planned target could hit lending and economic growth
    significantly. For similar reasons, in Slovakia CB legislation has been recently amended41
    .
    The EBRD itself and most Member States consider having a framework at EU level in place
    an important blueprint on which modelling their legislation. According to the EBA, three
    Members States (AT, ES, IE) have informed that they intend to wait for the Commission's
    conclusions before taking any action. In another 9 jurisdictions no changes to national
    frameworks have been introduced (BE, CY, DK, FI, IT, LU, PT, SI, UK). Also in those cases,
    the expectation of EU action has played a role in postponing any adjustment.
    There is also another dimension of the uneven development of covered bond markets which
    relates to economies of scale and the size of issuers. Covered bonds are mainly issued by large
    banks, as setting up programs entails high upfront costs. Moreover, liquidity is important in
    covered bond markets42
    and the latter is largely determined by a certain minimum volume of
    bonds outstanding. Smaller transactions are possible although they typically require a higher
    coupon to reflect the lack of liquidity. This explains why issuing covered bond is currently a
    business mainly for large banks, as illustrated by the large size of covered bond issuers across
    the EU (on average above EUR200 bn). As a consequence, the benefits of covered bonds are
    currently often beyond the reach of smaller banks.
    37
    For more details on the risks of asset encumbrance, see section 5.3.2 on Indirect Costs (p. 60)
    38
    A covered bond market in PL has already developed. Legislation in RO has only recently been finalized. In
    EE, HR, LT, LV and SK the project is on-going. In EE, LT, LV the framework will be common.
    39
    As a matter of comparison: in DE this ratio was 81%, in IT 86%, in Denmark 32% (IMF data).
    40
    In Poland the planned deposit growth rate for last year was 8% and the actual one has been 5%.
    41
    In Slovakia the deposit to loan ratio was 106% at the end of 2016, while the planned growth in bank assets is
    18%.
    42
    For example, covered bond indices typically only include bonds with at least €500mn outstanding. Another
    example: the eligibility for ECB repo operations is frequently size dependent.
    19
    Undiversified investor base
    The main investors in covered bonds are banks and central banks (see section 2.1.1). The
    limited uptake from other financial institutions (e.g. insurance/pension/asset managers) is
    problematic from a CMU perspective, as it limits these firms from channelling funds to banks
    and through them to the real economy. The situation was different in the recent past. As figure
    4 above shows, before 2013 the combined share of investors other than banks was
    significantly higher. It has since declined, largely due to lower yields resulting from ECB
    purchasing programs. These have reduced the incentives of asset managers, pension funds and
    insurance companies to invest in covered bonds. This effect has been reinforced by the limited
    size of the market in some Member States and by fragmentation across the euro area. The lack
    of diversification also leads to prudential concerns, in terms of increased concentration of
    risks. If covered bonds end up being mostly acquired by other banks, this does not bring
    additional liquidity to the sector and concentrates credit risks within the sector itself, creating
    interconnectedness. It is therefore important to diversify the investor base in light of the
    temporary nature of the ECB's involvement, future financing needs of banks and to address
    prudential concerns.
    Untapped potential for investments across the Single Market
    There is an untapped potential for further development of cross-border investments across the
    EU single market. While cross-border investment in covered bond markets across the EU
    currently represents 60% of total covered bond investments, this figure needs to be better
    qualified43
    . Not only it overstates the cross border activity in the EU, but also the bulk of such
    investments come from countries with a strong covered bond tradition (e.g. Germany and
    Nordic countries). Germany is particularly dominant, accounting on average for 37% of all
    cross-border investments of which most go to Nordic countries. Finally, the most part of
    cross-border investments takes place across countries with similar covered bond and mortgage
    legislations (for example Nordic countries typically invest in other Nordic countries). All this
    leaves an untapped potential in terms of cross-border investments. Fulfilling this potential
    through a broader harmonized market would be important for issuers aiming at expanding the
    markets for selling their covered bonds both within and outside the Union. It would also be
    important for investors wanting to geographically diversify their portfolios..
    In the context of the public consultation conducted by the European Commission between
    2015 and 2016, many respondents confirmed that cross-border investment in covered bonds is
    “already taking place”, but many (insurers, investors, public authorities including the ECB)
    underlined that it faces significant legal or practical obstacles. Among them, a commonly
    highlighted issue referred to differences in legal frameworks which require prospective buyers
    to invest more in credit analysis and legal research. This may partly explain why the investor
    base remains home-biased and concentrated in markets with similar regulatory frameworks.44
    43
    This the average share in the EU of non-domestic investments (including extra-EU) in the primary market
    only in relation to covered bonds included in the IBOXX index (including the most tradable covered bonds
    with minimum issuance of EUR 500 million). It only considers the existing markets and in particular AT,
    DE, DK, FI, FR, IE, IT, NL, NO, PT, ES, SE, UK. Excluding countries where covered bond markets do not
    exist or are under developed, the figure overstates the cross border activity in the EU. The actual figure for
    the whole EU could be significantly lower and would therefore not represent a satisfying benchmark for a
    wholesale market.
    44
    For example, an important obstacle to cross-border investments is indeed the fact that bonds issued in
    different EU jurisdictions do not provide the same degree of investor protection. This is reflected by ratings
    which differ not only for the rating of the issuer and of the country, and for the quality of the cover pool, but
    20
    Certain respondents suggested that harmonisation could encourage and facilitate additional
    cross-border investment. The ECB, in responding to the public consultation on the CMU
    MTR, manifested concern for the low comparability of covered bonds across Member States
    and fragmentation in the markets, showing support towards an EU covered bond harmonized
    framework and the EBA's recommendations to that effect.
    Another aspect of the cross-border dimension is the existence of cross-border cover pools
    which could help lending across countries. Cross border cover pools allow lowering country
    risk concentration. This could help countries that do not currently have developed covered
    bond markets and where the small scale of mortgage operations may necessitate cross-border
    cover pools to achieve critical mass45
    . Nonetheless, cross-border cover pools remain very
    limited. Of 125 programmes rated by Fitch, only 21 included assets from jurisdictions other
    than the one in which the issuer was based. This minority represents EUR 70.3 billion, or 3.2
    per cent of the outstanding European covered bond market. Most were concentrated in four
    Member States (DK, FR, DE, and LU). Many respondents to the Open Public Consultation
    highlighted that there are significant legal or practical barriers to cross-border cover pools.
    For example, only a few jurisdictions have developed rules catering for this situation, e.g.
    specifying valuation methodologies for loans in other countries.
    Limited third-country investments
    The lack of a European covered bond regulatory framework might also hamper investment
    from third countries, as investors from outside the bloc do not have a comprehensive basis for
    comparison with the covered bond framework of their home jurisdiction. Currently,
    investments from outside the EU represent a small share of the market as only 11% of EU
    issued covered bonds are held outside the EU (ICF, 2017) compared to 16.5% of total debt
    securities (Commission estimates). This illustrates that covered bonds are underrepresented
    among investments from outside the EU. This issue will become more important in the
    medium term when the ECB support programmes will eventually come to an end. More third-
    country investments would help maintain good funding conditions for European banks.46
    However, it is unlikely that those kinds of investors will invest time and resources to perform
    due diligence of the different characteristics of more than 25 non-harmonised national
    regimes.
    Moreover, in absence of an EU harmonized framework it is also difficult to establish
    equivalence between jurisdictions and therefore allow for reciprocal recognition of
    preferential treatment. This could hamper foreign investors' interest in EU covered bonds and
    limit EU investors' range of interesting investment choices.
    2.2.2. Prudential concerns
    There are also prudential concerns associated with the preferred treatment enjoyed by covered
    bonds, given that EU law does not comprehensively define what covered bonds are and much
    is left to national legislation. As a result, the preferential treatment may be accorded to very
    different products depending on the Member State in question. Furthermore, where EU law
    also for the different level of investor protection and the different degree of pool transparency of each
    jurisdiction.
    45
    EBRD (2017)
    46
    Some EU covered bonds (for example German Pfandbrief) enjoy very good reputation also outside the EU
    and their level of safety is deemed similar to sovereign bonds. Covered bonds of a good quality have the
    characteristics to be purchased by central banks and other conservative investors e.g sovereign wealth funds.
    21
    exists it may not fully address potential risks related to covered bonds (CRR) or may not have
    stood the test of time in terms of financial innovation or regulatory developments, e.g. as
    regards state aid and resolution. This section further outlines those concerns. At the same
    time, it is commonly recognized that covered bonds performed well during the financial crisis.
    This should not give ground to complacency47
    , also taking into account the exceptional state
    support granted to the banking sector during the crisis. In forming a view on how the existing
    prudential rules perform, the Commission services have drawn on a variety of sources,
    including the two reports issued by the EBA in 2014 and 2016 as well as views expressed
    during the public consultation.
    Diversity in national covered bond frameworks and risk of misalignment with preferential
    prudential treatment
    As seen in section 2.1.2, the only piece of EU legislation that defines a covered bond is art. 52
    UCITS. However, this provision was not conceived for this broader purpose in mind, but was
    rather focused on extending the limit on investment concentration in some product offerings
    (including those that contain covered bonds) that were considered of higher quality. The
    UCITS definition in Article 52(4) has therefore never been intended to serve as the general
    definition of covered bonds as a financial instrument, but to ensure an appropriate level of
    protection to investors investing in UCITS compliant funds48
    . From this perspective, the
    UCITS definition contains only a few provisions for a debt instrument to be considered
    covered bond namely: i) the nature of the issuer; ii) the dual recourse principle; and iii) the
    special public supervision. It does not develop detailed provisions to define other structural
    features of covered bonds and is therefore not suitable to be considered a proper definition for
    an instrument having such a significant size and importance for the EU banking sector. Over
    time, covered bond instruments have further developed and contain elements that go beyond
    the narrow definition in UCITS. For instance, some covered bonds have extendible maturity
    structures such as the soft-bullet and conditional pass through, while others contain specific
    provisions on liquidity buffers or composition of the cover pool. These aspects are not
    captured by the existing provisions in UCITS. Instead, the structural characteristics of covered
    bonds are mainly defined in national legislations. This leads to a large diversity of covered
    bonds instruments across the EU.
    The EBA documents the current diversity in the national covered bond frameworks in legal,
    regulatory and supervisory terms. While there are similarities (e.g. related to dual recourse
    and the coverage principle), there are variations in the frameworks in the area of special
    public supervision as well as in relation to the disclosure of data, liquidity buffers,
    composition of the cover pool, and stress testing. In light of these differences, action at EU
    level may be necessary in order to ensure that the favourable treatment extended to covered
    bonds in EU legislation rests on solid ground.
    For example, in relation to public supervision, the EBA finds differences across the EU in the
    content and level of detail regarding the rules on special public supervision, scope of duties
    47
    It should also be noted that even if no covered bond defaulted during the crisis, there have been problems in
    the market. For example, selling the cover pool turned out to be longer and more difficult than expected in
    many Member States. In Spain, it took on average three years to sell assets of the cover pool. We cannot
    exclude, that, in the event of a future systemic crisis and absence of state bail-out funds, the length and
    complexity of the selling process would lead to missing payments towards bondholders and defaults.
    48
    Over time, given that the covered bond definition in UCITS was the only definition available at EU level,
    several legislations have relied on this definition, e.g. RTS on European Market Infrastructures Regulation
    (EMIR), Solvency II Delegated Regulation and LCR Delegated Regulation.
    22
    and the powers of supervisory authorities regarding ongoing supervision of covered bond
    issuers and programmes, as well as the rules on approval and licensing of covered bond
    programmes. Furthermore, the EBA notes that the divergences extend beyond regulatory
    frameworks and are also observed in actual supervisory practices of individual competent
    authorities in the execution of special public supervision. The elements of the regulatory
    framework related to the supervisory model have indeed potential credit impact as confirmed
    by rating agencies.49
    The EBA 2016 Report also shows that, since the publication of the EBA Best Practices on
    Covered Bonds in 2014, more than half of the responding jurisdictions (12 out of 22) have
    either not implemented any changes to their covered bond frameworks or action is on hold
    pending the results of the Commission’s review of the EU covered bond framework.
    Convergence has therefore not taken place in the recent years during which the process has
    been monitored.
    The diversity of national frameworks means that covered bonds with diverse characteristics
    benefit from the same preferential treatment. This may give rise to prudential concerns.
    Preferential capital treatment not adequate (art 129 CRR)
    When adopting the CRR in 2013, the legislators called on the Commission and the EBA to
    review whether the preferential capital treatment for covered bonds is adequate in light of the
    prudential risks. On the basis of a first report in 2014, the EBA concluded that art 129 CRR
    does not need modifications in terms of inclusion/exclusion of specific cover assets, but is less
    specific on equally relevant aspects of prudential treatment. In a second report in 2016, the
    EBA recommended that the CRR be strengthened in relation to (i) disclosure requirements for
    the issuer; (ii) rules on substitution assets; (iii) Loan-To-Value limits for cover assets
    collateralised on physical property (i.e. for mortgage cover pools); and, (iv) minimum over-
    collateralisation. The EBA also notes that existing provisions on the eligibility of cover assets
    for the capital preferential treatment should be reassessed. The Commission services share
    this assessment and believe that the treatment provided for in article 129 of the CRR is not
    adequate and that the conditions for accessing this treatment needs to be strengthened.
    Not addressing new risks resulting from financial innovation
    The combination of EU and national frameworks is inadequately equipped to deal with new
    risks presented by financial innovation. Financial innovation has, for example, prompted the
    increasing use of new structures, so-called Soft-bullet and Conditional Pass Through (CPT)
    programmes. These aim to mitigate liquidity risk through the introduction of long-term
    maturity extensions regarding repayments to bondholders.50
    These kinds of extendible
    49
    In particular, Moody's in its evaluation methodology for covered bonds lists the following: qualifications,
    duties and powers of the cover pool monitor; the modalities and scope of the supervision in going concern;
    the modalities and scope of the supervision in the event of the issuer’s insolvency/resolution; the
    characteristics, power and duties of the administrator of the covered bond programme post issuer’s
    insolvency/resolution.
    50
    Typically, covered bonds used to be hard bullet in the past i.e. they needed to be repaid at the scheduled
    maturity date. Any delay in the payments would have constituted a default event. Recently, however, more
    flexible maturity structures have been introduced in the market that allow for the possibility to extend
    maturities and repay covered bonds to bondholders later than the original scheduled maturity date. In
    particular, the extension of scheduled maturities might be 12 months (soft bullets), but can also be
    "conditional pass-through" (CPT) where the new final maturity date is set on the basis of the maximum
    maturity date of the cover pool assets which could translate in an extension of up to 30 years. The triggers
    23
    structures may involve a higher level of complexity, incorporate non-uniform features and
    introduce changes to the structural characteristics of the product, as the EBA recognizes. The
    new structures may pose new risks to investors in terms of liquidity. These risks may not be in
    line with the current preferential treatment.51
    Evidence suggests that covered bonds containing these new features so far represent a relative
    limited share of the overall market for outstanding covered bonds. However, their market
    share is increasing.52
    The fact that these features have increased structural diversity in the
    covered bond market is also the result of how they have typically been introduced – by
    contractual terms – rather than by regulation. While, within any given country, soft bullet
    structures seem relatively homogenous, there are differences across jurisdictions.
    that allow for invoking the extension may vary and can be at the discretion of the issuer or upon certain
    defined events, e.g. non-payment on the scheduled maturity date.
    51
    For example, the UCITS definition is not able to capture these aspects of maturity extension, as it contains
    no detailed rules on the structural features of covered bonds, including these aspects. Therefore, covered
    bonds featuring those extensions, despite their different liquidity risks, are considered as part of the
    traditional covered bond group and as such they enjoy preferential treatment.
    52
    There are currently €305 billion of soft bullet and €14 billion of CPT outstanding (only the benchmark
    bonds in the iBoxx index are included in these figures). Within this index they represent 41 per cent and 2
    per cent of the total of outstanding CBs respectively. These percentages are increasing over time because
    more newly issued covered bonds are in these formats and the number of conversion of existing bonds from
    “hard bullet” to “soft bullet” structures (typically after bond-holder consent solicitations) is increasing.
    24
    Figure 7. Problem tree
    Drivers Problems Consequences
    National frameworks
    defining different
    structural characteristics
    for covered bonds
    Prudential requirements
    not aligned with structural
    characteristics of the
    product: financial risks
    Preferential capital
    treatment not adequate:
    prudential concerns
    Prudential concerns:
    Financial risks, market
    integrity and investor
    protection
    Increased risks due to
    financial innovation
    Low level of investment
    in covered bonds from
    outside the EU
    Unevenly developed
    covered bond national
    markets
    Low diversification of
    investor base
    Untapped potential for
    EU cross-border
    investment
    Untapped CMU
    Potential:
    Restricted financing and
    investment options, leading
    to reduced capacity of the
    banking sector to finance
    the wider economy
    Differences in national
    legal frameworks on
    covered bonds and lack
    of frameworks in some
    MS
    -> legal uncertainty and
    informational problems
    for investors
    Requirements for
    capital preferential
    treatment not adequate
    Financial innovation
    (soft bullets/CPT)
    Out-of-scope drivers:
    - ECB covered bonds programme
    - investor and issuer preferences
    - market conditions
    - macroeconomic developments
    - etc.
    25
    2.3. The EU's right to act and justification
    The Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union confers to the European institutions the
    competence to lay down appropriate provisions that have as their objective the establishment
    and functioning of the internal market (Article 114 TFEU).
    The previous section demonstrated that covered bonds are unevenly developed across the
    Single Market and that there is an untapped CMU potential. It also highlighted that covered
    bonds are only partially addressed in EU law, which may give rise to prudential concerns. To
    address these two concerns, action at EU level is warranted.
    First, concerning the CMU potential, the EU level is the most effective to address significant
    differences in national regulatory frameworks, diverging practices in the market and at
    regulatory level by Member States, fragmentation in the Single Market and lack of
    harmonization that hamper cross-border investments. These problems can best be tackled at
    EU level.
    Second, as regards prudential concerns, these stem from the fact that what constitutes a
    covered bond is not comprehensively addressed in EU law. The only definition of covered
    bonds at EU level is in the UCITS directive. That definition was, however, not drafted with
    this broader purpose in mind but had a more limited scope and is not considered to
    sufficiently ensure convergence of the structural characteristics of the product across the EU
    with the level of risk implied by the favourable EU treatment. As a result, covered bond
    structural characteristics are mainly defined at national level and these regimes vary
    significantly. Harmonising national frameworks would ensure that the structural
    characteristics of the product are the same across the Single Market. EU action appears the
    most effective way to achieve that objective. Also in this second area, problems can therefore
    best be tackled at EU level.
    The Public consultation, the 2016 EBA Report, the resolution of the European Parliament and
    subsequent discussions with Member States in e.g. the Financial Services Committee of the
    Council and the European Commission Expert Group on Banking, Payments and Insurance
    show that stakeholders in general welcome a further harmonisation in form of a directive
    building on well-functioning national systems. A directive represents, indeed, the best means
    to achieve the stated objectives while respecting the principle of subsidiarity. A number of
    Member States have also put on hold changes to national covered bond-legislations, which
    also show that they expect further harmonisation at EU level.
    3. OBJECTIVES
    In light of the concerns outlined in the previous chapter, two general objectives will be
    pursued, which in turn can be articulated into specific objectives:
     Enhance CMU potential, leveraging banking capacity to support the wider economy:
    a harmonised EU framework for covered bonds would enhance their use as a stable and
    cheaper source of funding for credit institutions, especially where markets are less
    developed, in order to help financing the real economy in line with the objectives of the
    CMU. This would translate into the following specific objectives:
    – Contribute to the development of covered bonds markets in EU countries where they
    do not exist or are less developed. Expanding the scope of covered bond markets, is
    26
    not only to be intended from the geographical perspective, but also in terms of
    issuers size;
    – Diversify covered bonds' investor base;
    – Tap the potential for more cross border investments; and
    – Attract investors from third countries.
    This will be particularly important when the ECB ends its covered bond purchase
    programme and the monetary stance eventually becomes less accommodative. Credit
    institutions will then be more in need of cheap and long-term sources of funding to finance
    the real economy;
     Address prudential concerns and ensure the coherence of preferential prudential
    treatment: national frameworks need to be strengthened and harmonised in order to
    ensure that the preferential treatment provided for under EU legislation is aligned with the
    level of risk implied by the structural characteristics of the instrument. This would translate
    into the following specific objectives:
    – Define the structural features of covered bonds in EU law in order to align the
    structural characteristics of covered bonds across the EU with the risk features
    underlying the EU preferential treatment;
    – Strengthen the requirements for benefitting from preferential capital treatment under
    the CRR; and
    – Define a framework for newly developed liquidity structures (Soft-bullets and
    Conditional Pass-Through (CPT) programmes).
    Table 3 – Intervention logic diagram
    Problems and consequences Objective
    Consequence 1
    Untapped CMU potential – Restricted financing
    and investment options, leading to reduced capacity
    of banking sector to finance the wider economy.
    General Objective 1
    Enhance CMU potential - Leveraging banking
    capacity to support the wider economy.
     Problem 1: Unevenly developed national
    markets
     Specific objective 1: contribute to develop
    covered bond markets in all EU countries
     Problem 2: undiversified investor base  Specific objective 2: diversify investor base
     Problem 3: Obstacles to cross border
    investments
     Specific objective 3: tap the potential for
    more cross border investments
     Problem 4: Low levels of investments
    from outside the EU
     Specific objective 4: attract investors from
    outside the EU
    Consequence 2
    Prudential concerns – Financial risks, market
    integrity and investor protection
    General Objective 2
    Ensure the coherence of EU prudential regulation
    with the structural characteristics of covered bonds
     Problem 1: diversity in national covered
    bond frameworks and risk of misalignment
    between EU preferential treatment and risk
    characteristics of covered bonds
     Specific objective 1: Define the
    structural features of covered bonds in EU
    law in order to align the structural
    characteristics of covered bonds across the
    EU with the risk features underlying the EU
    preferential treatment
     Problem 2: requirements for capital
    preferential treatment not adequate
     Specific objective 2: strengthen the
    requirements for benefitting from preferential
    capital treatment in CRR (art 129)
     Problem 4: increased risks due to financial  Specific objective 4: define a framework for
    27
    innovation (soft bullets and CPTs) new liquidity structures
    4. OPTIONS
    This section will examine the policy options available to achieve the above objectives. The
    baseline scenario consists of the current status quo (i.e. no action). There will then be a range
    of options that differ in terms of intensity of harmonisation, spanning from a non-regulatory
    option to options involving full harmonisation. More specifically:
     Baseline: do nothing;
     Option 1: Non-regulatory option;
     Option 2: Minimum harmonisation based on national regimes;
     Option 3: Full harmonisation replacing national regimes; or
     Option 4: 29th
    regime operating in parallel to national regimes.
    The four options listed above will all be assessed in the following. In addition, the final part of
    this section outlines an option (adjusting the preferential prudential treatment) that has been
    discarded as it would significantly disrupt existing markets and lacks any stakeholders'
    support.
    This section explores the main advantages and disadvantages of the options listed above. For
    ease of reference, the following policy-option matrix (table 4) summarises each of the
    available options (rows) along with the related policy areas to be addressed (columns). Each
    cell specifies the level at which each area will be settled. The first column is about the
    structural characteristics that a covered bond must have (for example dual recourse,
    segregation of cover assets and bankruptcy remoteness of the cover pool). The second column
    is about what assets should be allowed in the cover pool (especially in terms of traditional vs
    non-traditional assets). The third column is about how covered bonds should be supervised.
    Such "special public supervision" is another fundamental characteristic of covered bonds. The
    fourth column is about whether or not EU covered bonds should be granted a label. The fifth
    column is related to the preferential treatment that covered bond investors enjoy under EU
    law (cfr section 2.1.2). The sixth column is related to transparency requirements. Finally, the
    last column concerns all the other technical aspects spanning from overcollateralization levels
    to cover pool derivatives and liquidity risk mitigation tools. Each of the four options
    considered will cover all the policy areas in the columns with a different degree of
    harmonisation.
    Table 4 – Policy-option matrix
    Structural
    features
    a)
    Cover
    pool
    b)
    Supervision
    c)
    Label
    d)
    Preferential
    treatment
    e)
    Transparency
    f)
    Technical
    aspects
    g)
    Baseline Mainly
    national
    National National Market EU Market National
    Option 1 Mainly
    national
    National National Market EU Market National
    Option 2 EU National
    and EU
    National +
    basic EU rules
    EU EU revised/
    strengthened
    EU Principles at
    EU level +
    details at
    national level
    Option 3 EU only EU National/SSM +
    detailed EU
    EU EU revised/
    strengthened
    EU Principles +
    details at EU
    28
    rules level
    Option 4 EU
    (national
    for parallel
    regimes)
    EU
    (national
    for
    parallel
    regimes)
    National/SSM +
    detailed EU
    rules
    EU EU revised/
    strengthened
    EU Principles +
    details at EU
    level (national
    for parallel
    regimes)
    In designing these options, the Commission services have taken due account of the views
    expressed by various stakeholders and in particular the 2016 advice of the EBA and the 2017
    report of the European Parliament.
    The EBA advice
    In their 2016 Report, the EBA suggests a ‘three-step approach’ to the harmonisation of
    covered bond frameworks in the EU:
    (1) Step I: develop a principle-based covered bond framework, which would aim to
    provide a definition of the covered bond product as an instrument recognised by the
    EU financial regulation (implementation via directive is recommended). This would
    be the central point of reference for prudential regulation purposes;
    (2) Step II: targeted amendments to the CRR provisions on covered bonds, which would
    aim to enhance conditions for the access to preferential risk weight treatment of
    covered bonds;
    (3) Step III: use of non-binding instruments with a view of stimulating voluntary
    convergence between national frameworks in specific areas considered less critical in
    terms of alignment with preferential prudential treatment, and, at the same time, also
    the most controversial among Member States.
    Overall, the EBA approach is advocating for minimum harmonisation. The EBA approach
    intends to be principle based and to build on the strengths of the existing national frameworks,
    while, at the same time, ensuring more consistency in terms of definition and regulatory
    treatment of covered bonds in the EU. It should however be noted that some stakeholders,
    including Member States, have expressed the view that the 2016 EBA report, in some
    instances, goes beyond the advocated principle-based approach and gets into a high level of
    details on some issues (e.g. liquidity requirements).
    The EP Report
    Overall, the EP Report shares the EBA approach to covered bond harmonization, except for
    some elements. For example, the EP report proposes a common definition of covered bonds
    based on two labels: some covered bonds would become Premium Covered Bonds (PCBs)
    and others would remain Ordinary Covered Bonds (OCBs). In addition, the Parliament also
    proposes to create a new category of covered bonds to be named European Secured Notes
    (ESNs) based on SMEs loans or non-government-backed infrastructure loans.
    4.1. Baseline: do nothing
    The baseline scenario implies no action at EU level. The structural features of covered bonds
    would therefore continue to be regulated mainly at national level with the exception of the
    few elements imposed by the UCITS Directive (Art. 52). The current preferential treatment
    would remain in place. The Best Practices published in 2014 by the EBA would continue to
    serve as a reference point for the coordination of Member States regulations, but they would
    remain voluntary. The industry could continue or intensify its ongoing initiatives of voluntary
    29
    standardization. While the definition of an industry-led EU covered bond label is already in
    place in relation to transparency requirements (see work of European Covered Bond
    Council53
    ), in the future the industry could provide standardisation also in the field of defining
    market standards for new maturity structures. Another market push in the direction of
    harmonisation could come from credit rating agencies' requirements as issuers tend to comply
    with them to get better ratings.
    Under this scenario:
    a) Structural features: The structural features of covered bonds would remain regulated
    at national level;
    b) Cover pool: The cover pool would remain regulated at national level. However, for
    covered bonds eligible for capital preferential treatment, assets are explicitly listed in
    art 129 CRR;
    c) Supervision: The characteristics of the supervision model would remain regulated at
    national level;
    d) Label: The labelling process would be market-driven;
    e) Preferential treatment: Preferential treatment would remain regulated at EU level in
    different pieces of EU law (see section 2.1.2);
    f) Transparency: Transparency requirements would remain mainly market driven.
    However, for covered bonds eligible for capital preferential treatment under article
    129 CRR, transparency requirements would remain explicitly listed in the same
    article; and
    g) Technical aspects: Other technical aspects would remain regulated at national level.
    Under the baseline scenario, covered bonds issuance is expected to increase in the short term.
    According to a survey by the EBA, EU banks indeed plan to increase covered bond issuance
    in 2018 and 2019 after below average supply in 2017.54
    However, this only affects the largest
    and established EU covered bond markets. Substantial increases compared to 2017 of the
    order of 50% are expected in Sweden, Germany, Denmark, France, Italy and Spain. The main
    driver is the expectation of increase in overall debt issuance in the banking sector for the next
    couple of years. The latter is due to the winding down of central bank funding and to
    improved economic conditions. According to Credit Agricole analysis, spreads are expected
    to widen by around 20-30bp on the back of tapering.
    In relation to the main problems identified in section 2.2, under the baseline we would expect:
     CMU potential – Problem 1: a few countries with no legislation in place would undertake
    legislation in line with EBA best practices. It is unlikely that all countries would comply
    with EBA best practices, as empirical evidence has already shown. Even if issuance in the
    largest and well-established market is expected to increase compared to 2017 (see above),
    no uptick in issuance is expected in less developed markets.
     CMU potential – Problem 2: the increase in yields of around 20-30bp on the back of
    tapering (see above) would likely have the effect of attracting investors other than banks
    53
    The European Covered Bond Council (ECBC) is the platform that brings together covered bond market
    participants including covered bond issuers, analysts, investment bankers, rating agencies and a wide range
    of other interested stakeholders. The ECBC currently has over 100 members across more than 30 active
    covered bond jurisdictions globally. The ECBC represents over 95% of covered bond issuers in the EU.
    54
    EBA (2017). The EBA survey is based on a sample of 155 banks from all EU countries asking about their
    funding plans for 2017-2019.
    30
    such as insurers and asset managers. The latter have partly retreated because of the ECB
    purchasing programmes and should find it easier to recover their demand should the
    CBPP3 step back and the yields widen thus proving more attractive for them.
     CMU potential – Problem 3: no significant changes are expected in this respect and the
    cross-border activity is expected to remain the same and taking place mainly between
    countries with similar jurisdictions (see section 2.2).
     CMU potential – Problem 4: no significant changes are expected in this respect. In the
    absence of any EU regulatory framework for covered bonds, it would be difficult to assess
    equivalence with third country regimes. This would hamper investments by third countries.
    It would also restrict the choice for investors based in the EU. Moreover, the increased
    issuance coupled with the likely reduction or ending of the ECB CBPP3 could cause
    difficulties for issuers in placing their issuance on the market.
     Prudential concerns – Problem 1: the process of harmonisation would not necessarily
    take place or would take place only slowly, mainly driven by market forces. In some areas,
    a process of divergence could be envisaged for example in relation to market innovations.
    This could increase prudential concerns associated with the preferential treatment, the
    conditions of which would remain unchanged. This could undermine the international
    credibility of EU covered bonds. An eventual reduction of preferential treatment would
    imply costs to the market (see section 4.6).
     Prudential concerns – Problem 2: the inadequacy of requirements for capital preferential
    treatment under art 129 CRR could undermine the international credibility of EU covered
    bonds. An eventual reduction of preferential treatment would imply costs to the market
    (see section 4.6).
     Prudential concerns – Problem 3: the proliferation of market innovations might lead to
    increased divergence across Member States. For example, the increase in the issuance of
    soft bullet and CPT could replace the whole market in some countries and not in others (in
    Germany all issuance is hard bullet whereas other jurisdictions such as Italy currently only
    issue soft bullets). This would widen differences across Member States in terms of the
    structural characteristics of the product and make the rationale for preferential treatment
    still more difficult to defend.
    4.1.1. Advantages
    The baseline would imply no disruption of the status quo and no costs of adaptation and
    transition. Member States would retain their own models and related specificities. This would
    help preserving the functioning of at least those markets already working well. In the absence
    of EU action, market bodies might try to regulate the market themselves (e.g. by developing
    further standardisation practices). In addition, in the absence of EU action, Member States
    might also change their laws to conform to EBA best practices. At the same time, credit rating
    agencies could induce issuers to comply with international standards (e.g. EBA best practices)
    independently of national rules.
    4.1.2. Disadvantages
    Voluntary convergence is no guarantee of effective and coherent harmonization. Moreover,
    market-based voluntary arrangements aimed at harmonising certain market practices in the
    form of self-regulation are unlikely to constitute a sufficiently robust basis for maintaining
    over time the preferential prudential treatment currently conferred on covered bonds.
    Moreover, as any convergence would be voluntary, there is no certainty that actors in the
    market would comply. In addition, there is no guarantee that market standardisation goes in a
    31
    prudentially sound direction: the content of market standards would indeed be beyond the
    control of regulators and could deviate from EBA best practices. Finally, there would be no
    covered bond label at EU level in regulatory terms, but only national labels. All the above
    elements hamper both the achievement of further stimulating market development (objective
    1) and addressing prudential concerns (objective 2).
    4.2. Option 1: Non-regulatory action
    Under this option, harmonisation would be encouraged on a voluntary basis through the use of
    soft tools such as the issuance of recommendations by the Commission. This would
    accompany and support what has already been done by the EBA and the ECBC (see baseline
    scenario). The backing by the Commission would provide further encouragement for Member
    States and issuers to align with the recommended best practices. No legislative initiative
    would be undertaken under this scenario.
    This option is not in line with the EBA advice and with the EP Report as both ask the
    Commission to legislate. This option only partly overlaps with the third step of the EBA
    approach where compliance is left to voluntary convergence. However, for the EBA, this step
    should only concern minor areas considered less critical in terms of alignment with
    preferential prudential treatment.
    Under this option:
    a) Structural features: The structural features of covered bonds would continue to be
    regulated mainly at national level;
    b) Cover pool: The cover pool would continue to be regulated at national level. For
    covered bonds eligible for capital preferential treatment, assets would remain
    explicitly listed in article 129 CRR;
    c) Supervision: The characteristics of the supervision model would continue to be
    regulated at national level;
    d) Label: The labelling process would be market-driven;
    e) Preferential treatment: The preferential treatment would continue to be regulated at
    EU level;
    f) Transparency: The transparency requirements would continue to be market driven.
    For covered bonds eligible for capital preferential treatment under article 129 CRR,
    transparency requirements would continue to be explicitly listed in the same article;
    g) Technical aspects: Other technical aspects would continue to be regulated at national
    level.
    The main difference with the baseline would be the active role the Commission would take
    alongside the EBA in issuing recommendations and best practices. In addition, market
    standards would continue to play an important role and could be further strengthened by the
    Commission backing.
    4.2.1. Advantages
    The main advantage of this approach is that it would minimise any potential disruption on the
    functioning of the current regimes and the related costs compared to all other options. From
    the regulatory side, Member States would have more scope to retain their own models
    compared to other options. This would help preserve the functioning of at least those markets
    already working well. EU recommendations could provide backing both to the EBA Best
    32
    Practices and to market-led self-regulation initiatives. This could encourage Member States
    drafting sensible covered bond frameworks and align them with EU recommended best
    practices. This in turn would help achieving objectives 1 and 2.
    4.2.2. Disadvantages
    The disadvantages of this option are very similar to those of the baseline. As illustrated above,
    the use of non-binding tools and self-regulation has limits. That undermines the willingness
    and ability of operators in less developed covered bond markets to conform to an EU
    recommended framework. This, along with the lack of an EU label, would in turn hamper
    further market development (objective 1) and in particular the potential to develop not
    existent or very small markets. It would also not help enhance cross-border investments and
    attract more investments from third countries. At the same time, those jurisdictions where
    covered bond features are not coherent with the risk level implied by the EU-wide preferential
    treatment would be allowed to leave their frameworks as they are. The prudential concerns
    would therefore not be addressed (objective 2).
    Moreover, this option has been discarded by a large majority of institutional stakeholders,
    among them notably the EBA, the European Parliament and the ECB as an ineffective way of
    achieving harmonisation. The majority of other stakeholders have underlined that market-led
    initiatives are valuable but insufficient. At the beginning of the consultation process, a
    majority of market stakeholders (in particular issuers) was in favour of this option. However,
    after the EBA published its advice, clarifying the contours of a possible EU legislative
    initiative, industry views have evolved, as testified by the ECBC position. Accordingly, only a
    minority of market stakeholders remain in favour of non-legislative action.
    4.3. Option 2: Minimum harmonization based on national regimes
    Under this option, a harmonised legal framework for covered bonds would be established at
    EU level. This EU framework would aim at a minimum level of legislative harmonization
    across the EU, building on the characteristics of existing national jurisdictions and seeking to
    avoid disrupting well-functioning markets. Under this option, the structural features that
    covered bonds must respect in order to be labelled as such would be harmonised to ensure that
    a minimum set of common basic structural rules become applicable across the Single Market.
    The specificities of well-functioning national markets would be taken into account and
    accommodated as far as possible. Where possible, harmonisation would remain principle-
    based, minimising detailed provisions to the strict minimum. Member States would therefore
    retain some room of manoeuvre to devise their own laws on how to reach the goals set out in
    the directive. This would allow national specificities to remain in place, provided they are
    compatible with the principles defined in the EU framework. Under this option, Article 52 of
    UCITS would be replaced by a new Directive defining the structural elements of covered
    bonds. This would become the new point of reference for other pieces of EU legislation and
    would be the only EU definition of what is a covered bond. Among those pieces of law,
    Article 129 CRR would also be adjusted in order to strengthen the conditions for accessing
    the preferential capital treatment.
    This option is in line with the EBA advice and with the EP Report as both ask the
    Commission to legislate and to define (through a directive) the structural features of covered
    bonds at EU level, remaining principle based and respecting the characteristics of national
    markets. Concerning the overall approach and most of the specific recommendations for each
    policy area, option 2 comes close to the EBA advice. In particular, this option follows the
    33
    three-step approach defined by the EBA. However, there are differences between option 2 and
    the EBA Report, notably as regards the level of detail and prescription as option 2 would not
    go as far as sometimes suggested by the EBA.55
    Regarding the EP Report, option 2 is in line with the EP position concerning the approach
    (principle based) and the legislative means (directive). However, also in this case, in some
    areas the level of details of the proposal by the EP is too high for a principle-based approach.
    Moreover, the EP Report defines three labels: PCBs, OCBs and ESNs sharing common basic
    features and being part of the same legislative initiative. This is not endorsed by the
    Commission that has already decided that while the ESN is promising, given the particular
    risk characteristics of SME loans, it requires a dedicated impact assessment separate from that
    of covered bonds.
    Under this option,
    a) Structural features: The structural features of covered bonds would be regulated at
    EU level through a dedicated directive. The very high level principles contained in art
    52 UCITS would be replaced by a new self-standing directive that would define the
    structural elements a covered bond must comply with. This directive would also serve
    as a point of reference for the several pieces of EU law that grant preferential
    treatment to investments in covered bonds. It would regulate key elements like for
    example the dual recourse mechanism, the need to segregate cover assets and ensure
    the bankruptcy remoteness of the cover pool.
    b) Cover pool: The cover pool would be regulated both at EU and national level, with
    principles set at EU level and implementing measures at national level. As is the case
    today, the new instrument would not list what types of assets can be used in the cover
    pool in the context of the directive, nor explicitly exclude any of them (status quo
    compared to Art. 52 UCITS). It would nevertheless define principles56
    that guarantee
    the high quality level of the assets in the cover pool, allowing for some flexibility for
    the Member States to decide on their preferred assets. At the same time, as it happens
    today, assets are strictly listed in art 129 CRR in order to identify the subgroup of
    covered bonds which are granted preferential capital treatment. Under option 2, the
    situation concerning article 129 CRR would stay the same as in the baseline with the
    possibility to reassess some kinds of assets currently listed in art 129 such as ships.
    Assets, such as SMEs and infrastructure loans, which most likely would not fit the
    principle of asset eligibility set out in the defining directive, could be considered part
    of the ESN initiative targeted at creating a new instrument (see section 1). In terms of
    cover assets, the new directive would also extend the possibility to use pooled covered
    bond structures i.e. covered bonds using as cover assets other covered bonds or pooled
    assets in order to let small issuers enjoy economies of scale. Finally, under this option,
    the new directive would envisage the removal of all legal obstacles to cross-border
    cover pools;
    c) Supervision: General principles of special public supervision would be defined at EU
    level specifying the areas that the special public supervision should cover while
    55
    While the EBA declares to be principle-based, in certain areas (e.g. liquidity requirements) it effectively
    suggests very detailed provisions which would better suit a full harmonization regime (option 3). Therefore,
    while the EBA advice broadly corresponds to option 2, there are some elements in it that would better fit
    with option 3.
    56
    Such assets would need to be of high quality and it should be possible to determine either their market or
    mortgage lending value. In addition, requirements on the legal enforceability would need to be met in order
    to ensure that the cover assets can be repossessed.
    34
    leaving the choice to the Member States to decide on how such supervision should
    actually take place. Supervision principles also imply the definition of eligibility
    criteria for issuers. Supervisors will have to apply those principles when authorizing
    covered bond programs. Under this option, supervision would stay with national
    competent authorities.
    d) Label: Under this option, "European covered bonds" (EU CB) would become an EU
    label. Issuers would be able to (voluntarily) use this label when marketing their bonds,
    provided that the product complies with the requirements set out in the directive.
    Monitoring of compliance with the conditions under which such label could be legally
    used would form part of the special public supervision of the covered bond
    framework. An ex-ante control of the use of the label would not be necessary, but
    supervisors should be able to withdraw its use when the conditions are not/or longer
    met (with possible sanctions). National denominations and labels would be able to stay
    in place and could be used simultaneously or alternatively, at the discretion of the
    issuer. Supervisors should periodically compile a list of EU CBs. This approach would
    differ from the one recommended by the EP report where two different labels would
    be granted to covered bonds: Ordinary CBs (OCBs) when compliant with the directive
    and Premium CBs (PCBs) when compliant with both the directive and article 129
    CRR. Such double label does not appear necessary to promote the EU legislation
    among investors and would risk creating confusion as to the actual nature and quality
    of the different instruments.
    e) Preferential treatment: Preferential treatment would only be granted to covered
    bonds compliant with the requirements set out in the directive. In some cases (for
    example for the CRR art 129 capital preferential treatment) additional conditions
    would need to be met to become eligible for preferential treatment. In particular, the
    conditions of eligibility for preferential treatment in the CRR for investors in the
    banking sector would be strengthened, following advice by the EBA57
    , by introducing
    additional rules on substitution assets, minimum overcollateralization and by revising
    rules concerning eligible cover assets and LTV limits.58
    f) Transparency: transparency requirements in the form of increased disclosure,
    frequency and granularity would be set in the directive;
    g) Technical aspects: other technical aspects would be considered mostly in the form of
    principle based provisions leaving leeway to Member States to translate those
    principles into more detailed requirements. For example, principles would be defined
    in the directive to establish liquidity requirements or specific conditions for maturity
    extensions.
    57
    In their 2016 Report and in previous Opinions, the EBA assessed that, from the prudential point of view, the
    requirements set out in art 129 CRR need to be strengthened. See section 2.2.2
    58
    Concerning preferential treatment for investors in the insurance sector envisaged in Solvency II,
    Commission services do not have any new data or evidence sufficient to justify a change from a prudential
    perspective. Moreover, the existing risk calibrations for covered bonds are already favourable compared to
    corporate bonds. One can argue that flexible maturity features increase the risk of cash flow uncertainty to
    insurers as investors. While, at this stage, there is no evidence that the calibration needs to be changed, it is
    possible that a new asset category will need to be created and the relevant ESA (EIOPA) will be asked for
    advice on the calibrations. Concerning the preferential treatment for UCITS investors, which is a waiver on
    a concentration limit, there is no evidence suggesting this must be changed and no technical advice by ESAs
    has been produced in this respect. While no change would be directly introduced to the prudential regime
    applicable to UCITS and insurance companies investing in covered bonds, those would nevertheless benefit
    from the additional level of harmonisation and strengthening of investor protection envisaged in the new
    directive. Finally, concerning pension funds, there is not currently an EU framework on quantitative capital
    requirements for occupational pension funds, so it is impossible to envisage a preferential treatment at EU
    level for pension funds investing in covered bonds.
    35
    4.3.1. Advantages
    This approach would respect the national characteristics of those markets already working
    well as advocated by all stakeholders (especially Member States). This option would be in
    line with what is envisaged by the EBA and the European Parliament. In general, all
    stakeholders in the public consultation advocated a principle-based approach building on the
    characteristics of existing national frameworks already working well. A minimum level of
    harmonization would help developing markets and stimulate cross-border investments, in line
    with objective 1. At the same time, it would make the framework more robust from the credit
    point of view and this would better underpin the preferential treatment envisaged in EU
    legislation, so meeting objective 2. This option carries a lower disruption potential compared
    to options 3 and 4, as recognized by Member States and stakeholders and would lower
    transition costs as compared with options 3 and 4. Overall it is more in line with subsidiarity.
    Finally, the strengthening of the eligibility conditions for the preferential prudential
    framework for banks investing in covered bonds would also strengthen the international
    credibility of the preferential treatment accorded to covered bonds.
    4.3.2. Disadvantages
    Being too principle-based could imply the risk of not providing an effective harmonisation, if
    national rules do not properly reflect the principles. This would not help develop markets and
    cross-border investments as per objective 1. At the same time, leaving Member States too
    much flexibility might present the risk of them making more hazardous choices, for example
    in terms of assets to be allowed in the cover pool. This would hamper achieving the objective
    of addressing prudential concerns (objective 2). The main challenge with this option would
    therefore lie in how to achieve a proper balance between a principles-based approach and
    more detail where necessary. In addition, this option also entails adaptation costs compared
    with the baseline and with option1 (see section 5).
    4.4. Option 3: Full harmonisation
    This option would involve the design of a new fully harmonised regime for covered bonds at
    EU level. In contrast to option 2 (minimum harmonisation), this option would establish a fully
    harmonised EU framework for covered bonds that would replace existing national regimes. It
    would define every detail of a sound covered bonds regulatory framework. It would also be
    different from option 4 to the extent that it would replace national regimes instead of flanking
    them. The legislative instrument envisaged to implement this option would be a regulation.
    This option differs both from the EBA advice and from the Parliament Report as both ask the
    Commission to define (through a directive) the structural features of covered bonds at EU
    level, remaining principle based and respecting the characteristics of national markets. A full
    harmonization instead would be very detailed, leaving no space to Member States for
    adaptation and would risk disrupting markets that are currently working well. Option 3 also
    departs from the EBA three steps approach. In spite of all the differences, there are, however,
    some similarities between option 3 and the EBA Report. The very detailed provisions
    envisaged in certain areas would fit with this option better than with option 2. Overall,
    however, option 3 foresees a much more detailed harmonisation of rules compared to the ones
    advised by the EBA and proposed by the Parliament.
    Under this option,
    36
    a) Structural features: the structural features of covered bonds would be defined at EU
    level. A comprehensive definition would focus on the structural features a covered
    bond must have in order to seek regulatory recognition (for example in terms of dual
    recourse mechanism, segregation of cover assets and bankruptcy remoteness of the
    cover pool) and would replace the covered bond-related provisions in UCITS
    Directive. This would be similar to option 2, except for the fact that all rules would
    need to be very detailed, not just enouncing principles, but also accompanying them
    with operational details as this framework would replace all the existing national ones.
    b) Cover pool: in terms of cover assets allowed in the cover pool, they would need to be
    explicitly listed, thus significantly limiting Member States leeway in this area. It
    would be necessary to make specific choices on the kind of traditional or not
    traditional assets allowed in the cover pool. In case only traditional assets are allowed,
    the need to launch a parallel and separate instrument based on SMEs and infrastructure
    loans (ESN, see section 2.1) would become urgent. Coverage requirements would
    need to be defined in details. A similar provision allowing pooling structures for cover
    pools (as in option 2), would be introduced in order to let small issuers enjoy
    economies of scale. Finally, similarly to option 2, also under this option the regulation
    would envisage the removal of all legal obstacles to cross-border cover pools.
    c) Supervision: supervision would remain with national competent authorities for the
    less significant institutions and for banks outside the euro area, while it would go to
    the SSM/ECB for the largest banks in the euro area. This would be the consequence of
    pursuing full harmonization. Related level 2 legislation would be required to ensure
    consistent application of the legal framework. In that respect, the duties of the
    supervisors would need to be spelled-out in detail for instance in terms of the way
    covered bonds programmes would need to be authorised.
    d) Label: a labelling process would be put in place similarly to option 2. In this case,
    however, the EU label would replace all the existing national labels.
    e) Preferential treatment: same changes of the provisions governing the preferential
    treatment as in option 2.
    f) Transparency: transparency requirements would change as in option 2.
    g) Technical aspects: other technical aspects would have to be included in the EU
    framework with a sufficient degree of detail to make them operational. Differently
    from option 2, there would be no leeway in how Member States implement those
    detailed requirements, as the regulation would be directly applicable. A significant
    amount of level 2 legislation would likely be required.
    4.4.1. Advantages
    As this framework would include detailed proposals for every aspect of covered bond
    operations, there is less risk that Member States might not implement uniformly the rules
    defined in EU law. This uniformity would help develop markets, as it would provide to every
    jurisdiction in the EU an immediate tool to be used to develop their markets. It would also
    enhance cross-border investments and international attractiveness of covered bonds. Overall it
    would strengthen the CMU related dimension as per objective 1. At the same time, as
    Member States would not be allowed the flexibility to make more risky choices, for example
    in terms of assets to be allowed in the cover pool, the risk characteristics of the instrument set
    at EU level would be perfectly aligned with the preferential treatment set at the same level
    and this coherence will help achieving objective 2.
    37
    4.4.2. Disadvantages
    Both institutional and market stakeholders responding to the public consultation have warned
    that detailed harmonisation along the lines of this option could have unintended negative
    consequences, especially for well-functioning markets, neutralising possible benefits.
    Designing a new framework for covered bonds would imply a more significant disruption of
    the status quo with the risk of damaging those markets already working well, even if a
    transitional period may partly mitigate these concerns. Under this option transition costs
    would be the highest compared to all other options, especially for those jurisdictions not
    aligned with the characteristics of the instrument at EU level. Designing a proper transitional
    phase would be more challenging than for options 2 and 4.
    A large majority of respondents to the public consultation as well as public stakeholders
    involved in the process, from the EBA to the Parliament, have suggested this option would be
    too disruptive to well-functioning markets entailing too high costs for credit institutions and
    for the overall functioning of financial markets.
    4.5. Option 4: 29th
    parallel regime
    This option would be very similar to option 3 with the difference that instead of substituting
    the current 28 regimes with a new one as envisaged in option 3, the newly created regime
    would co-exist and operate in parallel and compete with the existing 28 ones, becoming the
    29th
    regime. Differently from option 3, the new regime, if successful, could be expected to
    gradually replace the existing ones instead of directly superseding them from the outset. This
    replacement would happen on the basis of voluntary adoption by actors in the market.
    This option is not in line with the EBA advice and with the EP Report. Neither of the two
    suggested implementing a 29th
    regime.
    Under this option, the content of the new regulatory framework would largely resemble the
    one under option 3:
    a) Structural features: the structural features of covered bonds would be defined at EU
    level through a regulation. This would be similar to option 3, except for the fact that
    this regulation would not supersede the existing national legislations, but would flank
    them.
    b) Cover pool: in terms of cover assets allowed in the cover pool, they would need to be
    explicitly listed, thus significantly limiting Member States leeway in this area. This
    would be similar to option 3.
    c) Supervision: supervision would remain with national competent authorities for the
    less significant institutions ad for the banks outside the euro area, while it would go to
    the SSM/ECB for the largest banks in the euro area similarly to option 3. Related level
    2 legislation would be required to ensure consistent application of the legal
    framework. It would be similar to option 3 except for the fact that competent
    authorities would have to supervise two separate regimes: the national one and the
    European one.
    d) Label: a labelling process would be put in place similarly to option 3. In this case,
    however, the EU label would flank the existing national labels instead of substituting
    them.
    e) Preferential treatment: concerning the preferential treatment two sub-options would
    be available. 4.1) Neutral approach meaning existing EU rules granting preferential
    38
    treatment (UCITS, CRR, Solvency, LCR, EMIR) would stay in place and continue to
    grant preferential treatment not only to EU covered bonds issued under the 29th
    regime, but also to covered bonds issued under national frameworks, as is the case
    now. However, this may not provide sufficient incentives for market participants to
    use the new 29th
    regime. 4.2) Providing incentives to pursue the maximum take up of
    the 29th
    regime meaning the current preferential treatment at EU level would need to
    be reserved exclusively to the 29th
    regime with high costs of disruption of existing
    markets.
    f) Transparency: transparency requirements would change as in option 3.
    g) Technical aspects: other technical aspects would have to be included in the EU
    framework with a sufficient degree of detail to make them operational as in option 3.
    A significant amount of level 2 legislation would likely be required.
    4.5.1. Advantages
    A 29th
    regime would offer an off-the-shelf comprehensive regulatory framework to issuers
    wanting to use an EU label for attracting investors. Member States with no or with
    underdeveloped covered bond markets could be expected to use the new regime. This option
    would offer flexibility to issuers who would be able to choose between issuing under their
    existing national regimes or the 29th
    regime. Finally this option should offer the benefit of
    providing a fully integrated regime for issuers on a voluntary basis and would not require any
    amendments to existing national covered bond laws.
    4.5.2. Disadvantages
    The main risk of this option would be that the market development and prudential objectives
    set out above would not be achieved due to a limited market take-up, especially under sub-
    option 4.1. Its adoption by market participants is indeed based on a voluntary choice and there
    is no guarantee this regime will become the standard at EU level, especially in well stablished
    markets where issuers and investors alike highly value their systems. However, as outlined
    above, the 29th
    regime could take off in less developed covered bond markets. This could
    cause fragmentation in the EU internal market and would also increase costs as different
    regimes would run in parallel. In addition, the survival of several well-established regimes
    plus the 29th
    would confuse investors and increase complexity.
    To overcome the issue of a limited take up and related fragmentation, incentives would need
    to be provided as for sub-option 4.2. However, this would be politically contested. Both sub-
    options present high costs, with no obvious compensating benefits. All the above has been
    recognized by stakeholders by all sides both from institutions and the market. A large
    majority of respondents to the open public consultation have rejected this option. This option
    builds on market participants adopting the new market practice to be successful. Given the
    scepticism expressed by all stakeholders, this is unlikely to be the case. This option is
    therefore unlikely to meet the objectives set out above.
    4.6. Discarded option: adjusting the prudential treatment
    A logical alternative that can be considered, at least to address prudential concerns, would be
    to adjust the preferential prudential treatment, instead of harmonising the structural
    requirements of the instrument.
    39
    However, adjusting preferential prudential treatment could only mean downsizing it, if one
    wants to address the prudential concerns highlighted above. The preferential treatment
    currently granted can be considered the maximum acceptable deviation from international
    standards (for example Basel). Repealing or limiting the prudential treatment would have
    disruptive effects on existing markets. According to ICF59
    , the effect of the loss of preferential
    capital treatment for covered bonds can be estimated by observing the differential in yields
    between CRR compliant and non-CRR compliant covered bonds by the same issuer. A
    reliable example of this is provided by two series of bonds issued by the same Danish issuer.
    The spread in the yields between a CRR compliant and a non-CRR compliant covered bond
    both issued by the same issuer with the same maturities range between 4.8 and 21.1 basis
    points (average 12.0, timeframe considered November 2014-July 2015) where the higher
    yield is attached to the non-CRR compliant bond. This could provide an estimate of the
    benefits investors attach to the preferential treatment. The latter does not only concern CRR
    capital weighting, but also other forms of preferential treatment granted to covered bonds by
    EU legislation such as the LCR preferential treatment for liquidity purposes (see section
    2.1.2). While it is difficult to accurately estimate the effect on yields of a lower or no
    recognition of the asset class in the LCR delegated act60
    , it is possible to use again a Danish
    example to provide an estimate of the spread in yields between bonds classified as level 1 and
    2A61
    which amounts to 2 basis points and, between 2A and no eligibility at all, which amounts
    to 7 basis points62
    . Also in this case, non-eligibility for preferential treatment translates into
    higher yields for investors and higher costs for issuers. For issuers therefore, losing
    preferential treatment would translate into several basis points of increased cost of funding.
    This option does not have any stakeholder support among the industry, but also among
    supervisors and it was not even mentioned in the EBA Report nor in the Parliament Report.
    Considering the significant disruption it would cause to well-functioning markets with no
    apparent compensating benefits and considering also the lack of stakeholders support, this
    option is discarded and won't be assessed.
    The ultimate purpose of adjusting the preferential treatment would be to better target it at
    those covered bonds that exhibit risk characteristics coherent with the preferential treatment.
    Accordingly, judgements would need to be made on the features of an instrument that makes
    it less risky. In the end this approach would also be concerned with assessing structural
    features of covered bonds, albeit in an indirect way and would imply harmonization via the
    back-door. However, the harmonization of structural characteristics in one single piece of
    legislation (as envisaged under the four options above) appears a more efficient and coherent
    way to tackle prudential concerns.
    59
    ICF, 2017, pp. 48-49.
    60
    As the factors that cause them to be recognized for preferential treatment are themselves price sensitive it is
    difficult to isolate the effect of the LCR treatment.
    61
    The LCR requires that the liquidity buffer is made up of assets in the following categories: Level 1, Level 2a
    and Level 2b. The levels not only determine the maximum eligibility of securities for being part of the
    buffer (Level 1 to an unlimited extent, but at least 60% of the overall buffer; Level 2a maximum 40% and
    Level 2b maximum 15%), but also the haircut that applies to the market value. Under certain circumstances,
    covered bonds can be classified either as Level 1 or Level 2a or 2b.
    62
    ICF Report, 2017, p. 49.
    40
    5. ASSESSMENT OF POLICY OPTIONS
    This section assesses the benefits and costs of the proposed options both at aggregate level
    and by relevant stakeholder groups. It will assess the benefits, of both direct and indirect
    nature, against the general and specific objectives outlined in section 3.
    In order to assess how the different options fare with respect to the first general objective of
    tapping CMU potential, the section starts by presenting benchmarks that define the maximum
    benefits that can be expected from having harmonized EU covered bond markets. Similarly, a
    benchmark is provided for the direct costs arising to covered bond issuers, investors and
    supervisors. As regards the second general objective, addressing prudential concerns, the
    extent to which prudential concerns would be addressed under each option is more difficult to
    assess against a quantitative benchmark.63
    The assessment of the benefits and costs of each
    option against that objective will accordingly be of more qualitative nature.
    In addition, the options will be assessed in terms of (1) how effective they are in achieving the
    objectives; (2) how efficient they are in light of associated costs; (3) how coherent they are
    with broader EU policies; and (4) how they affect key stakeholders (issuers; investors;
    supervisors; and, citizens).
    The retained policy option will be one ensuring the best possible achievement of the stated
    objectives, while at the same time imposing the smallest costs and impacts on stakeholders
    and enjoying their support and being coherent with broader EU policy objectives.
    Figure 8 summarizes the methodology followed to identify the retained option.
    Figure 8. Methodology for assessing benefits and costs and choose the retained option
    63
    To give an idea of the size of the concern, it could be noted that 32% of covered bonds are owned by banks
    which means almost €700 billion of assets in EU banks' balance sheets are investments in covered bonds.
    41
    5.1. Benchmark benefits and costs
    The extent to which markets are likely to develop (objective 1) under each option will be
    measured through the following "benchmarks" that define the maximum benefits for each
    concerned dimension:
    a) Number of countries adopting a covered bond framework in line with EBA best
    practices;
    b) Additional issuance of covered bonds;
    c) Savings in terms of funding costs for banks issuing covered bonds;
    d) Overall savings in funding costs for the real economy;
    e) Diversification of the investor base;
    f) Share of cross border investments in covered bonds;
    g) Share of covered bonds held outside the EU.
    A similar approach will be followed to assess the costs of each option. The benchmark costs
    are derived from the costs currently borne by stakeholders in those jurisdictions which are
    more in line with the potential EU framework. In particular, the following benchmarks will be
    provided for the different categories of costs: (1) direct administrative one-off costs; (2) direct
    administrative recurrent costs; and, (3) enforcement costs. The different options will then be
    assessed in relative terms compared with benchmark costs.
    5.1.1. Benchmark benefits
    This section further outlines the specific benchmarks that would be used for assessing the
    options. Table 5 further below summarises the benchmarks benefits and their relationships
    with specific objectives.
    a) Number of countries adopting a covered bond framework in line with EBA best practices
    The benchmark for this benefit is represented by the maximum number of Member States
    required to introduce or amend their covered bond legislation in order to comply with the
    EBA best practices. According to the EBA, only one Member State (NL) complies in full.64
    The benchmark number would therefore be 27. This includes countries needing less
    significant amendments, countries needing an overhaul of their legal framework and countries
    needing to introduce a totally new framework from scratch. Under the baseline, one could
    expect eight countries to take action in order to comply with the EBA best practices. Based on
    the EBA Report, there are four countries that are already amending their national frameworks
    (CZ, FR, EL, and SK). In addition, other Member States have recently decided to set up a
    legislative framework (EE, LT, LV and HR).
    b) Additional issuance
    The Commission services estimate that the total size of the currently untapped market
    potential for covered bond across the EU in terms of issuance could be up to EUR 342
    billion. This figure is based on the assumption that a fully harmonised regime could increase
    the use of covered bonds up to the benchmark level of 8.5 % of total loans in all EU Member
    States currently below that benchmark. The benchmark has been calculated as the median
    value of the ratio of covered bonds to total bank loans currently observed among Member
    64
    EBA (2016).
    42
    States with established markets.65
    The benefit in terms of additional issuance would
    significantly accrue to new markets (EUR 63 billion out of EUR 342 billion). This share
    represents about one fifth of additional issuance, significantly above the current share of the
    same markets out of the outstanding total (1.3%). Annex 4 presents further details on these
    figures.
    Under the baseline, the size of benefits in terms of additional issuance would be around one
    quarter of the benchmark or around EUR86 billion (less than proportional, considering the
    only large country in the sample would be France). This is confirmed by EBA analysis66
    ,
    according to which long-term secured funding for EU banks is expected to grow from
    EUR1.5 trillion in 2016 to approximately EUR1.6 trillion in 2019. 84% of this figure would
    be represented by covered bonds.
    c) Savings in terms of funding costs for banks issuing covered bonds
    The Commission estimates that the total savings in terms of funding costs for EU banks
    issuing covered bonds are between EUR 2.2 billion and EUR 2.7 billion on an annual
    basis67
    . This figure is based on three main assumptions:
    (1) that a fully harmonised regime could increase the use of covered bonds up to the
    benchmark level of 8.5 % of total loans in all EU Member States (see benchmark b);
    (2) that covered bonds provide a funding benefit in the range between 30 bps and 45 bps
    compared to unsecured funding68
    ;
    (3) that a strengthened regime would result in an additional 5 bps funding benefit on all
    covered bonds, as estimated by the commissioned study (ICF, 2017).
    While this figure should be seen as a benefit for all banks in the EU, the specific benefit for
    the countries where covered bond markets are already well developed is mainly linked to the
    third component (EUR1.1 bn). On the contrary, for new markets this benefit is mainly related
    to the issuance of covered bonds instead of unsecured bonds. Issuers in new markets would
    save between EUR 200 million and EUR 300 million on an annual basis in the long term.
    Annex 4 presents further detail on how these figures have been obtained.
    Under the baseline, one could expect the size of benefits in terms of savings for banks would
    be around one quarter of the benchmark i.e. between EUR 0.5 billion and EUR 0.7 billion on
    an annual basis.
    d) Overall savings in borrowing costs for the real economy
    1. Lower funding costs are likely to be at least partially passed through to customers,
    freeing resources to be lent to households and firms. This would create wider benefits for the
    real economy. The Commission estimates that the potential overall annual savings for EU
    65
    See Annex 4 for further details on how this figure has been obtained.
    66
    EBA (2017a). The EBA survey is based on a sample of 155 banks from all EU countries asking about their
    funding plans for 2017-2019.
    67
    This benefit should be seen as a long-term benefit based on the assumption that the outstanding will be
    rolled over and gradually replaced by new issuance at lower interest rates. This implies that the benchmark
    benefit is not expected to be achieved immediately after the entry into force of the legislation. In the first
    years following entry into force, savings would result lower than the expected benchmark and their size
    would depend on the amount of yearly issuance.
    68
    Savings for banks should be seen as gross of the increased costs related to issuing covered bonds (see
    section on benchmark costs).
    43
    borrowers would be between EUR 1.5 and EUR 1.9 billion69
    . This figure has been
    obtained considering the savings in terms of funding costs for banks issuing covered bonds as
    calculated in point c) and using the estimated long-term pass-through rate by Illes et al. (2015)
    of about 70%.
    The economic literature has extensively assessed how credit institutions' funding costs get
    translated into lending rates for the real economy. According to the prevailing consensus, this
    pass-through effect does function relatively well over the medium- to long-term, even though
    the short-term adjustment is imperfect70
    . Illes et al. (2015) identify a stable positive
    relationship between lending rates and bank funding costs for European countries both in the
    euro area and outside the euro area71
    over the period 2003–2014, comprising the pre-crisis and
    post-crisis periods. They estimate this pass-through rate at around 70%. The bulk of existing
    studies use samples of banks in advanced economies. It could be argued that thanks to the
    existence of a single banking rulebook applicable across all EU Member States, banking
    models of central and eastern European countries would become more structurally similar to
    the rest of Europe. In addition, some studies suggest that heterogeneity in the banking rates
    pass-through exists only in the short run (Gambacorta, 2008). The estimate of the pass-
    through provided by Illes et al. (2015) can therefore be deemed acceptable across all Member
    States.
    Under the baseline, the benefits in terms of overall savings for the real economy would be
    around one quarter of the benchmark i.e. between EUR 0.4 billion and EUR 0.5 billion on an
    annual basis.
    e) Diversification of the investor base
    The cumulated share of investments in covered bonds by banks and central banks amounted
    to 63% in 2016 (see section 2.1.1.). In the baseline scenario one could assume that this share
    would go down to 50% in light of the end of the ECB purchasing programme (see section 4,
    baseline). This forecast seems relatively conservative given past experience.72
    In addition, one
    could expect that a unified EU covered bond markets would add another 10% to the share of
    covered bonds purchased by financial institutions other than banks. Taken together, this
    would bring the benchmark to 60%.
    Under the baseline, the only effects in terms of diversification would come from the gradual
    phasing out of the ECB purchasing programme (around 50% of investors other than banks).
    There would be no further effects resulting from e.g. further market integration.
    f) Share of cross-border investments
    A proxy for the level of development of cross-border investments is represented by the share
    of inward investments in a Member State coming from other Member States out of the total of
    the covered bond market in that Member State. This share varies significantly: from 92% for
    the UK to 28% for Germany.73
    A possible estimate of a benchmark for cross-border
    investments would therefore be provided by the median of these values equal to 73%.
    69
    Similar considerations hold as for banks' savings (benchmark c) for which see note 66.
    70
    For example, see Banerjee et al. (2013); Gambacorta (2008); Borio and Fritz (1995); De Bondt (2002);
    Hofmann and Mizen (2004); De Graeve et al. (2007); Kwapil and Sharler (2010); Darracq-Paries et al.
    (2014).
    71
    The total sample refers to: AT, DE, DK, ES, FI, FR, IE, IT, NL, PT, UK.
    72
    For example, in 2013 the year before the CBPP3 started, the share held by banks and central banks was 48%
    73
    ICF (2017a), p.30. This ranking only takes into account established covered bond markets.
    44
    Currently, most cross-border investments take place between countries that share similar
    characteristics in terms of covered bond legislation and property valuations standards. For
    example, in Finland almost three quarters of foreign investments come from Germany and
    other Nordic countries and in other Nordic countries this share is about two thirds (see section
    2.1.1). It is difficult to foresee the effect of better harmonization at EU level for this regional
    integration of covered bond markets. However, the trend could go in the direction of lowering
    this share in order to better diversify the number of different countries investing in a given
    market. This would provide benefits in terms of less concentration, further financial
    integration and improved financial stability.
    Under the baseline, cross-border investments would likely stay close to or slightly above the
    current level with slight improvements in some countries such as the Baltics if they decide to
    undertake a common legal framework. This would, however, represent a small percentage of
    the benchmark.
    g) Share of covered bonds held outside the EU
    The benchmark for the level of investments by third countries in the EU covered bond
    markets can be assumed to be the same as the level of investments by third countries for all
    debt securities issued in the EU which is estimated at an average of 16.5%. Currently the
    share as regards covered bonds is only 11% (see section 2.1.1). Hitting the 16.5% benchmark
    would translate into an additional EUR 115 billion of investments in EU covered bond
    markets coming from outside the EU on a multi annual long term horizon74
    .
    Under the baseline, third-country investments would likely stay at the current level.
    Table 5 – Intervention logic diagram + benchmarks
    Problems and consequences Objective Benchmarks
    Consequence 1
    Untapped CMU potential
    General Objective 1
    Enhance CMU potential
    Problem 1: Unevenly developed
    national markets
    Specific objective 1: develop
    covered bond markets in all EU
    countries
    a) Number of countries adopting a
    framework
    b) Additional issuance
    c) Savings of funding costs for
    banks
    d) Overall savings in borrowing for
    the real economy
    Problem 2: undiversified
    investor base
    Specific objective 2: diversify
    investor base
    e) Diversification of the investor
    base
    Problem 3: obstacles to cross
    border investments
    Specific objective 3: tap potential
    for more cross border investments
    f) Percentage of cross-border
    investments
    Problem 4: low levels of
    investments from outside the EU
    Specific objective 4: attract
    investors from outside the EU
    g) Percentage of covered bonds
    held outside the EU
    Consequence 2
    Prudential concerns
    General Objective 2
    Coherence of EU prudential
    regulation
    Problem 1: diversity in national
    covered bond frameworks
    Specific objective 1: align the
    structural characteristics of covered
    No measurable benefit
    74
    This number is based on the assumption that the average of 16.5% would be applied to the current
    outstanding covered bonds, not considering additional issuance. The result has to be seen as a multi annual
    long term benefit. The yearly amount has not been estimated.
    45
    bonds across the EU
    Problem 2: capital preferential
    treatment not adequate
    Specific objective 2: strengthen
    the requirements for capital
    preferential treatment in CRR
    No measurable benefit
    Problem 3: increased risks due to
    financial innovation
    Specific objective 3: define a
    framework for soft bullets/CPTs
    No measurable benefit
    5.1.2. Benchmark direct costs
    Issuing covered bonds implies significant one-off and recurring costs (due to establishing and
    running a covered bond programme), which are a function of several factors. Among them: (i)
    the size of the covered bond programme; (ii) the structure of the covered bond issuer; and (iii)
    country specific factors such as legal and supervisory requirements. It is possible to
    distinguish three main types of direct costs: (a) the initial costs of setting-up a covered bond
    programme; (b) the ongoing (annual) costs of running a covered bond programme; and (c) the
    costs of single issuance.
    a) Direct administrative one-off costs
    The upfront costs of setting up a covered bond programme, as estimated in the ICF study75
    ,
    comprise the following:
     Cost of setting up IT systems to support the administration and management of the
    programme including risk management, monitoring and reporting of the cover assets;
     Legal fees including the cost of a prospectus;
     Application and registration fees i.e. the cost of registering the programme with the
    regulator or supervisor;
     Investment bank fees: these are typically a function of maturity of the bond e.g. for a
    standard five year deal, investment banking fees would be of the order of 0.2% of the
    amount raised. Sometimes, an issuer does not pay any fees on the basis of an agreement
    that the issuer will use the investment bank for the first few bond deals and/or give that
    bank a disproportionate amount of the total fees payable on them; and
     Rating agencies’ fees: a minimum set-up and first issuance fee of €65,000 (limited
    approach) to €100,000 (full approach) for Eastern EU issuers and €70,000- €150,000 for
    Western EU is charged by Fitch Ratings. S&P charges a standard fee of €85,000 for annual
    surveillance of a covered bond programme.
    Total costs vary significantly between countries and banks, depending on the business model
    and on different arrangements not only with private parties but also with supervisors.76
    For example, Denmark is the country where the upfront costs are the highest due to their
    specific business model based on specialist credit institutions and to the specific supervisory
    model which is very comprehensive and totally paid by banks (costs ranging between EUR2.2
    million and EUR3.8 million per programme). The situation in other Nordic countries such as
    Sweden and Finland is similar. In France, upfront costs range between EUR1.6 million and
    EUR2.3 million. In Italy, they vary between EUR400,000 and EUR1.5 million. In the UK,
    75
    2017, ICF, pp.174-175.
    76
    For example, in Denmark the supervisor charges the banks for the cost of their comprehensive supervision.
    Danish banks do not have the choice to outsource some of the costs to external providers.
    46
    between EUR750,000 and EUR3.4 million. Estimates for Germany are only partially
    available. However, it is possible to infer that costs belong to the upper hand of the spectrum.
    On the other hand, there are countries with lower upfront costs such as Luxembourg
    (EUR100,000-350,000), Netherlands (EUR330,000-825,000), Belgium (EUR430,000-
    510,000) and Eastern European countries (for example Poland is around EUR400,000). The
    median of the minimum and maximum value is respectively EUR590,000 and EUR1.8
    million and could be considered a benchmark for one-off direct costs. In this case, however,
    the benchmark has to be seen as the value towards which low-cost jurisdictions would
    converge, while high-cost jurisdictions are not expected to decrease their costs and would
    therefore not converge towards the benchmark.77
    Under the baseline, out of the eight Member
    States expected to take action, four (CZ, FR, EL, SK) are not undertaking changes that would
    significantly modify their current structure of one-off costs, while only the other four (EE,
    HR, LT, LV) are expected to increase their one-off costs towards the benchmark, while
    keeping the increase at a minimum. Overall, this would result in a very small move towards
    the benchmark.
    b) Direct administrative recurrent costs
    These costs typically include78
    :
     Staffing costs for running the covered bond programme;
     Costs of back office operations, including IT maintenance: these can be expected to be
    negligible once a covered bond programme has been set-up involving monthly running of
    reports or checking of accounting entries. Smaller issuers with less sophisticated IT
    systems might need to carry out manual intervention, in which case these would involve at
    most 0.5 full time equivalent;
     Cost of the cover pool monitor: this depends on whether the cover pool monitor is
    mandatory and if his tasks are carried out by external providers or by the supervisor;
     Cost of professional bodies e.g. ECBC (EUR8,000 per year) and national industry body;
     Cost of the covered bond label comprising the initial registration fee of EUR5,000 payable
    with the registration of a new cover pool, an annual fee for the label of EUR3,800 in
    subsequent years, an additional volume issuance fee of EUR1 per million of new issuance
    (capped at EUR5,000 per year; not payable on the first year of a new Label), the fees and
    expenses of the Bond Trustee and Security Trustee (if any), ranging from EUR7,500 to
    EUR72,600.
    Total costs vary significantly between countries and banks, depending on the banking model
    and on different arrangements not only with private parties but also with supervisors. For
    example, in Denmark they are quite high, at around EUR2.2 million on an annual basis,
    because supervisory costs are paid annually by banks on top of their administrative costs. In
    France, they range between EUR0.5 and 1.8 million per year. In the UK, between EUR0.4
    and 2.8 million. In other Member States, ongoing costs are lower, ranging between less than
    EUR100,000 (Italy and Portugal) and EUR475,000 (Netherlands).
    The median of the minimum and maximum value ranges between EUR300,000 and
    EUR475,000 and could be considered a benchmark for recurring direct costs. In this case,
    77
    The costs related to setting up and running a covered bond programme come from ICF (2017). For more
    details on direct one-off costs, see Annex 5.
    78
    Estimates based on ICF (2017), in particular pp.175-177.
    47
    however, the benchmark has to be seen as the value towards which low-cost jurisdictions
    would converge, while high-cost jurisdictions are not expected to decrease their costs and
    would therefore not converge towards the benchmark.79
    Under the baseline, out of the eight
    Member States expected to take action, four (CZ, FR, EL, SK) are not undertaking changes
    that would significantly modify their current structure of recurring costs, while only the other
    four (EE, HR, LT, LV) are expected to increase their recurring costs towards the benchmark,
    while keeping the increase at a minimum. Overall, this would result in a very small move
    towards the benchmark.
    The costs associated with each issuance belong to the same category of recurrent costs. They
    typically include the following80
    :
     Rating fees: Fitch rating charges fees on all covered bond issuance as a percentage of the
    total issue size. The fees range from 0.25 bps (limited approach) to 1.0 bps (full approach)
    in Western EU countries. A flat rate of 0.5 bps is charged in Eastern European countries. It
    should be noted that issuers often get 2-3 ratings for their issues;
     Legal fees per issue is typically either nothing or a very small amount, but for a small
    number of issuers (in particular those who do not issue from a standard programme), these
    could range from €100,000 to €300,000;
     Fees and expenses incurred in connection with the listing of the covered bonds on stock
    markets. These can range from €4,000 in UK to €150,000 in Sweden.
     Fees relating to ISDA documentations (Swaps), which depends upon the number of
    counterparties an issuer has;
     In some countries, audit fees are payable per issuance (for instance, in Hungary this
    represents about €20,000 per issue).
    Issuance costs mainly depend on the size of the issuance, vary significantly from one issuance
    to the other and are negligible compared to total costs and as a result there is no dedicated
    benchmark.81
    Overall, the costs of setting up and running a covered bond programme are quite high, and
    generally higher than issuing unsecured debt. According to the German association of
    Pfandbrief Banks (VdP), while covered bonds allow banks to save on the cost of their
    funding, the high costs that issuing covered bonds entails imply that the breakeven point is
    around 20 basis points. This means that if banks save less than 20 bp when they issue covered
    bonds, instead of unsecured debt, covered bonds are no longer convenient. However,
    compared to securitization, covered bonds are still considered a more efficient source of
    funding for banks. This is because covered bond costs can be spread across several issuances,
    which eventually results in lower operational costs for each issuance of covered bonds. The
    advantage of a covered bond programme is indeed that once set up and registered, multiple
    transactions can be issued under the programme i.e., each new issuance benefits from the
    existing structure of the covered bond programme and bears only a negligible fraction of the
    total costs. In contrast, for securitisation, each new issuance entails new costs. Covered bonds
    are thus regarded as a more efficient funding tool by issuers. In addition, from an investor’s
    79
    For more details on direct recurring costs, see Annex 5. The costs related to setting up and running a covered
    bond programme come from ICF (2017).
    80
    2017, ICF, pp.177-178.
    81
    For more details on issuance costs, see Annex 5. The costs related to setting up and running a covered bond
    programme come from ICF (2017).
    48
    perspective, due diligence costs are lower for covered bonds, as it is a more standardised
    product.
    c) Enforcement costs
    To define a benchmark for enforcement costs two supervisory models are considered. One
    benchmark is represented by the Danish model which implies strong supervision and a
    comprehensive list of tasks all carried out by the supervisor itself with no possibility of
    outsourcing. Costs are borne by banks and annually paid to the supervisor. In Denmark,
    supervision of mortgage credit institutions (issuing covered bonds) is carried out by the
    Danish FSA. The Danish FSA does the following:
     Issuance of license: one off covered bond specific licensing;
     Periodic review and analysis of the data/documentation provided by the issuer82
    ;
     Periodic quality check of cover assets including checks on eligibility of assets and real
    estate valuations (including regular on-site visits);
     Periodic monitoring of the exposure of the covered bond programme to market risk and
    liquidity risk;
     Periodic checks of minimum mandatory over collateralisation requirements; and
     Evaluation of operational risks of the issuer.
    Around 17 FTEs across different departments of the Danish FSA are involved in supervising
    covered bond programmes (of which roughly 3.5 FTEs are involved in on-site inspections of
    covered bond issuers). The average salary cost per FTE is DKK650,000 (~ EUR87,400). In
    addition, the average overhead per FTE is DKK390,000 (~ EUR52,450). The annual costs
    incurred by the Danish FSA for supervising covered bonds issuers can be estimated at ~
    EUR2.4 million. Considering that there are only nine issuers in Denmark, the average cost of
    supervision per issuer would amount to EUR267,667. The average cost per covered bond
    programme can be estimated at EUR103,367 (based on ECBC data on the number of
    programmes equal to 23 in 2014 and 2015). The institutions under supervision pay for the
    costs associated with their supervision. The cost of running the Danish FSA is therefore,
    allocated to the different institutions under supervision based on different measures.
    The second benchmark is represented by the German model which is also characterized by
    strong supervision, however this is not entirely carried out by the supervisor itself. Some
    tasks, such as the monitoring of the cover pool, are exercised by external contractors. In
    Germany, Department BA 57 of the Federal Financial Supervisory Authority (BaFin) is
    responsible for conducting cover pool audits at Pfandbrief banks at two-year intervals, either
    using its own staff (appraisers), or Cover Pool Administrators (CPAs) experienced in the area
    of Pfandbrief cover pool audits (selected through a tendering process). The cost of cover pool
    audits conducted at two year intervals for the year 2015 was €718,000 for CPAs audits (17
    audits in 2015) and €224,000 for Bafin internal staff (8 audits in 2015). The average cost per
    audit was of €42,000 per CPAs and €28,000 for internal staff. Department BA 57 of Bafin
    total budget for 2015 was made up of direct costs of €1.55 million (of which direct staffing
    costs: €1.51 million) and overhead costs of €1.18 million for total costs of €2.73 million.
    Approximately 78% of Bafin BA 57 FTE is dedicated to covered bond supervisory activities.
    Assuming that a similar percentage of the budget is devoted to covered bond monitoring, this
    would mean that costs related to monitoring covered bonds amount to €2.13 million. While
    82
    For instance, reports of mortgage banks to the Danish FSA are provided on the quarterly basis and cover
    credit risk exposure, market risk exposure and solvency risk.
    49
    this figure looks similar to the Danish total, it differs in respect to what it includes. For
    example, Bafin outsources some audits to external auditors and it does not perform the duties
    of the cover pool monitor which are exercised by external contractors. On the contrary, the
    monitoring of the cover pool is part of the supervisory activity of the Danish FSA. As a result
    of these differences, but also of the different number of issuers which allows economies of
    scale in the German case, the average cost per issuer would be significantly lower in Germany
    (€25,350) than in Denmark (€237,745 - €264,161). The costs not recovered from Pfandbrief
    banks are funded as part of BaFin’s general budget (i.e. via cost allocation to supervised
    entities, where being a Pfandbrief bank would not imply specific treatment). For more details
    on supervisory costs see Annex 583
    .
    Among the two models, the German one could be considered the actual benchmark, as it is
    close to the model of supervision that fits with the harmonized framework and, at the same
    time, its costs are lower compared with the Danish model. However, not all countries could be
    expected to converge towards the German benchmark. For several Member States, this
    convergence would imply a significant increase in costs for supervisors. Many jurisdictions
    could rather be expected to converge half way, the extent of the convergence depending on
    the chosen option. For example, there are jurisdictions such as Austria, Cyprus, the Czech
    Republic, Italy and Slovakia, where supervision is carried out by the banking supervisor and
    is embedded in the general supervision of the issuing credit institution. Their costs can be
    estimated to be low and mingled with the costs of the overall banking supervision.
    Converging towards the benchmark would entail significant costs for those jurisdictions. The
    same holds for Member States with non-existing covered bond markets. Specific resources
    would need to be dedicated to perform the duties and tasks of a special public supervision on
    covered bonds along the lines of the harmonisation framework. The size of the increase would
    depend on the chosen option.
    Under the baseline, jurisdictions are expected to stick to their country model, therefore no
    convergence would be expected to take place towards the benchmark supervisory models.
    In the remainder of the Section, the different options are assessed as regards i) their
    effectiveness in achieving the stated objectives, and ii) their efficiency in terms of costs that
    are incurred while achieving them.
    5.2. Option 1 – Non-regulatory option
    Under this option, harmonization would be encouraged on a voluntary basis through the use
    of soft tools such as the issuance of recommendations by the Commission. There would be no
    legislative action.
    5.2.1. Benefits
    Direct benefits
    GO1 - Specific objective 1: without a coherent legislation establishing a framework for
    covered bonds at EU level, Member States would decide voluntarily whether or not to comply
    with recommended best practices. Member States with no framework in place could choose to
    stay without. According to the EBA 2016 Report, there are seven Member States that could be
    expected to take legislative action. They are the countries with amendments in progress (4:
    83
    ICF, 2017, Annex 6.
    50
    CZ, FR, EL, SK) and countries with legislation on hold pending a Commission decision on
    whether or not to propose legislation (3: AT, IE, ES). To this, one could add the three Baltic
    countries (EE, LT, LV) plus Croatia who have recently decided to set up a legislative
    framework. In total, one could expect 11 countries to take action in order to comply with the
    EBA best practices. The size of benefits in terms of additional issuance and lower costs of
    funding for banks and for the real economy could be expected to be around one third of the
    benchmark.84
    This would be lower than for the other options.
    GO1 - Specific objective 2: little investor base diversification would be expected except for
    the indirect consequence of the tapering of the ECB purchasing programme (see baseline
    scenario). However, this benefit will not be compounded by the benefit of a unified market.
    Therefore no additional benefit compared to the baseline is expected.
    GO1 - Specific objective 3: cross border investments would likely stay close to or slightly
    above the current level with slight improvements in some countries such as the Baltics if they
    deliver a common legal framework compliant with the best practices. However, this would
    represent a small percentage of the benchmark. Therefore, additional benefits compared to the
    baseline could be expected to be small.
    GO1 - Specific objective 4: third-country investments would likely stay the same. There
    would be no common third country regime (including equivalence provisions). The benefits
    of reciprocally recognising equivalence between third countries' regimes and the EU (as
    spelled out for option 2) would therefore not be achieved. No benefit expected compared to
    the baseline.
    GO2 - Specific objective 1: the benefit of aligning the structural characteristics of the product
    with prudential regulation at EU level would depend on the number of Member States that
    take action to comply with recommended best practices. If, as noted above, Member States
    expected to comply were 11 out of 27, this would not fully address the prudential concerns.
    Some benefits would be achieved compared to the baseline, but they would likely be small.
    GO2 - Specific objective 2: the CRR preferential capital treatment would not be changed. No
    benefit expected compared to the baseline.
    GO2 - Specific objective 3: the treatment of new liquidity structures (soft bullets and CPT)
    would depend on Member States. In absence of Member State intervention, contractual
    agreements or market standards could fill the void. The size of benefits would depend on the
    number of stakeholders choosing to comply and on the alignment between market standards
    and EU recommendations.
    Indirect benefits
    Leaving any adjustment to the discretion of Member States has the advantage of avoiding any
    possible disruption to national regimes that currently work well and the associated costs to
    that disruption.
    84
    Considering proportionality in this case has significant limits, however it can be considered acceptable a
    slightly lower than proportional effect as the group of countries is more biased towards small markets.
    51
    5.2.2. Costs
    As it is difficult to predict how many Member States would decide to comply and to what
    extent, a quantification of costs would be difficult. What could be reasonably inferred is that
    one would expect lower costs than under the other options.
    Direct costs
    Under option 1, the costs of setting up and running a covered bond programme would not be
    expected to change significantly compared with the baseline, as Member States would likely
    tend to preserve the status quo and eventually change it only gradually. As they would only
    act on a voluntary basis, Member States would not be expected to significantly increase costs
    in their markets. Under this option, out of the 11 Member States expected to take action, four
    (CZ, FR, EL, SK) are not undertaking changes that would significantly modify their current
    structure of one-off costs and recurring costs, while the other eight (AT, EE, ES, HR, IE, LT,
    LV) would be expected to converge towards one-off and recurring benchmark costs. They
    include Spain, where costs could be expected to change significantly if action is taken to
    comply with EBA best practices. Overall, this would result in a move towards around one
    third of the benchmark. Due diligence costs for investors would be expected to stay the same.
    As there would be no changes to the CRR framework, there would be no transitional costs or
    additional burden on investors from adapting to new capital rules. Banks investing in covered
    bonds would avoid the costs of having to adapt to a new regulatory environment, while
    supervisors would not have to adopt new supervisory approaches.
    Enforcement costs
    Supervisory costs borne by public authorities as a result of monitoring activities in each
    national jurisdiction would not significantly change compared to the baseline, as Member
    States would likely tend to preserve the status quo and eventually change it only gradually.
    This could be different in Spain. However, as option 1 is based on voluntary harmonization, it
    is not easy to predict to what extent changes introduced in that jurisdiction would comply with
    EBA best practices and how much they would contribute to increase supervisory costs.
    Overall, a slight convergence could be expected to take place towards the benchmark
    supervisory costs.
    Indirect costs
    Leaving the development of covered bond standards across the EU to Member States and
    market-led initiatives, presents the risk of covered bonds' structural characteristics diverging
    and hence does not fully address the prudential concerns. This may undermine the
    international credibility of EU covered bonds and could result in a rethink by EU regulators
    on the requirements and modalities of their preferential treatment. Downsizing or repealing
    the preferential prudential treatment could lead to disruptions in existing well-functioning
    national markets and to costs for issuers in terms of increased interest rates (see section 4.6).
    5.2.3. Overall assessment
    Effectiveness, efficiency, coherence
    The extent to which the stated objectives and related benefits would be accomplished depends
    on Member States' willingness to follow best practices. It would be up to them and banks to
    decide whether, when and how to implement the recommendations/guidelines. Even if
    Member States were to react quickly and introduce national legislation, a soft law action
    52
    would limit considerably the scope and depth of national initiatives. Moreover, without a
    coordinated effort, national initiatives are more likely to develop in different ways, potentially
    creating a set of different provisions and standards across the EU. This would change little
    compared to the current situation. As such, the incentive to issue and invest in covered bonds
    would remain limited to those Member States where markets already work well. At the same
    time, market-led mechanisms cannot guarantee the prudential treatment attached to covered
    bonds and without supervisors' overview, those standards would risk deviating in their content
    from what would be advisable from a prudential point of view. This option would minimize
    adaptation costs. However, low costs would be accompanied by low effectiveness in
    achieving the stated objectives, thereby suggesting this option would be scarcely efficient.
    The efficiency gained in the short-term by avoiding legislative action and minimizing
    adaption costs is outweighed in the longer term by the foregone benefits of a more coherent
    EU regime. Overall, the option would not guarantee the achievement of the objectives of the
    review in an effective, efficient and coherent way.
    Winners and losers
    On the basis of the above, Table 6 summarises the benefits and costs of option 1 for each
    category of stakeholders. Issuers would benefit from a partial lowering of funding costs and
    citizens would enjoy in their turn some lower borrowing costs as well. Costs would increase
    up to a limited measure for issuers and supervisors, while for investors and society no
    significant increase in costs is foreseen.
    Table 6 – Impacts on different stakeholders of Option 1
    Issuers Investors Supervisors Citizens
    Benefits ↑ ≈ ≈ ↑
    Costs ↑ ≈ ↑ ≈
    Stakeholder views
    While at the beginning of the consultation process, a majority of market stakeholders (in
    particular issuers) was in favour of this option, after the EBA Report has been published,
    clarifying the contours of a possible EU legislative initiative, only a minority of market
    stakeholders remained in favour of this option. The majority of them shifted towards
    supporting minimum harmonisation (option 2), as illustrated by the ECBC position.
    Moreover, option 1 is not favoured by a large majority of institutional stakeholders such as
    the EBA, the ECB, the Parliament, national and European supervisors. In addition many
    stakeholders, not only institutional ones, manifested their concern that market-led initiatives
    even if valuable could prove insufficient because they cannot be imposed on participants.
    While industry stakeholders consider the European "Covered Bond Label" a step towards
    better integration of the covered bond markets, most acknowledge that there are certain
    limitations to self-regulation, for example the fact that voluntary arrangements cannot form
    the basis for a specific regulatory treatment so need to be complemented by sound regulatory
    treatment at national or European level. Among Member States with the largest and well-
    established markets, France and Sweden used to be the two countries most sceptical of
    legislative action and most in favour of the non-legislative option.
    53
    5.3. Option 2 – Minimum harmonization based on national regimes
    Under this option, a legal harmonized framework for covered bonds would be established at
    EU level. This EU framework would aim at a minimum level of harmonization across the EU,
    building on the characteristics of existing national jurisdictions and seeking to avoid
    disrupting well-functioning markets. Under this option, the previous Article 52 of UCITS
    would be replaced by a new Directive defining the structural elements of covered bonds and
    Article 129 CRR would also be adjusted.
    5.3.1. Benefits
    Direct benefits
    GO1 - Specific objective 1: this option would imply mandatory national implementation of
    the objectives set out in the minimum harmonisation EU framework. All Member States
    would have to legislate in order to introduce a covered bond framework or to adapt the
    existing one to the requirements set out in the EU directive. This means achieving in full the
    benchmark benefit in terms of number of countries adopting a covered bond framework.
    However, the risk remains that the directive is not implemented completely, or that the
    national implementations leave a significant heterogeneity in the market given that Member
    States have a degree of discretion in how to implement the requirements set out in the
    Directive. It is reasonable to expect that once a coherent legislation is in place in each
    Member State along the lines of the Directive, this would stimulate the development of
    covered bond markets also in countries where currently they don't exist yet. The benchmark in
    terms of additional amount of covered bond issuance could be fulfilled if not fully, then to a
    large extent (one could expect between 50% and 75% of the maximum long-term benefit).
    As reported in section 2.2, a national legislative framework for covered bonds is one of the
    main factors at the base of the development of a florid covered bond market. This is also
    corroborated by anecdotal evidence. A case in point is Poland which did not have a covered
    bond market in the past, despite favourable economic conditions.85
    Another non-EU example
    where the development of a proper legislation has fostered the birth and development of a
    florid covered bond market is Canada.86
    Increasing the share of covered bond issuance, relative to unsecured debt, would help banks to
    lower the cost of their funding, again, achieving a large share of the estimated benchmark
    (between 50% and 75% of the maximum long-term benefit).
    The impact of an EU directive will not only be felt in less developed markets, but also in well-
    functioning ones. Among the latter, a direct benefit that could stem from the EU directive is
    the improvement in the credit characteristics of the instrument that would lead to
    85
    This was due to an outdated legal framework that lacked important structural features for investors'
    protection and was not aligned with EU standards. The EBRD provided technical assistance to the Polish
    Ministry of Finance to develop new covered bond legislation to update the old one and align it with
    European standards. The changes came into effect in 2016 and have been essential to foster covered bond
    issuance by Polish issuers allowing Polish banks to lower their reliance on deposits and on Western
    European parent companies. Currently, the Polish market stands at €2.2 bn of outstanding covered bonds
    having almost doubled between 2015 and 2016 from €1.3 bn.
    86
    In June 2012, the Canadian government approved covered bond legislation, providing a legal framework for
    its biggest banks to tap the market. Canadian banks flocked to issue covered bonds in euros and dollars
    which now represent an important source of capital flows into the country’s housing market. Covered bonds
    now finance nearly 10 per cent of the entire Canadian mortgage market, which is close to C$1.4tn in size,
    according to the Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation. That proportion was 5 per cent in early 2013
    and almost nothing in 2007.
    54
    improvements in their ratings and, therefore, to lower financing costs for issuers (see
    benchmark c). The specific benefit for the countries where covered bond markets are already
    well developed has been estimated by the Commission to amount to €1.1 bn annually. This
    figure has to be intended as part of the total benchmark benefit c).
    Expanding the scope of covered bond markets is not only to be intended from the
    geographical perspective, but also in terms of issuers' characteristics. The new framework
    would introduce measures to allow the use of pooled covered bond structures and encourage
    the issuance by smaller banks.
    GO1 - Specific objective 2: investor base diversification in line with the benchmark of 60%,
    could be reasonably achieved not only as an indirect consequence of the tapering of the ECB
    purchasing programmes as suggested in the baseline. Introducing mandatory strengthened
    requirements and more transparency for covered bonds would make the product safer and
    more attractive for more risk adverse investors such as asset managers, insurers and pension
    funds. At the same time, harmonizing the market would make the product more easily
    understandable and more liquid, attracting further all types of investors.
    GO1 - Specific objective 3: it can be expected that harmonisation through legislative means
    could encourage and facilitate additional cross-border investments. While it is difficult to
    predict to what extent the 73% benchmark (see benchmark f) would be achieved, an
    improvement in that direction could be expected compared to the baseline. In addition, an
    improvement also in terms of diversification of EU investors' geographic base in domestic
    markets could be expected as national systems would become more similar. This would be an
    advantage also for a well-established market like Germany which currently is the main
    investor not only in its domestic market but is also the main foreign investor in the EU with
    55% of all investments in the Union. Enlarging the choice of markets where German investors
    can find instruments of a similar credit quality to their Pfandbrief, would provide more
    investment opportunities for them and will help lower concentration risks.
    Another dimension of the cross-border objective is related to cover pools which should
    comprise assets coming from across the EU. Removing legal obstacles to cross-border cover
    pools, could increase their significance. This would be particularly relevant in small Member
    States where the small scale of mortgage operations may necessitate cross-border cover pools.
    For example cross-border banks will be able to lend to residents of small countries and
    include their mortgages in their cover pools. Moreover, pooling mortgages across geographies
    would represent a cost-efficient way to fund mortgages, offering, at the same time,
    diversification to investors.
    GO1 - Specific objective 4: it could be expected that a harmonized framework at EU level
    would reduce due diligence costs for third-country investors. Differences in legal frameworks
    across EU jurisdictions require greater investment in credit analysis and legal research to be
    able to analyse country-specific products. Increased comparability and transparency deriving
    from a legally harmonised framework may enhance third country investors' confidence in EU
    covered bonds and contribute to foster their investments in the European market. In addition,
    where third countries have similar covered bond frameworks in place, an equivalence regime
    might be envisaged for reciprocal recognition of preferential prudential treatment. If the EU
    preferential treatment is granted to covered bonds issued outside the EU, this would broaden
    the scope of EU investors' possibilities, providing more attractive risk/reward propositions for
    55
    them87
    . If, at the same time, third countries which have in place preferential treatment similar
    to the European one, decide that covered bonds issued in the EU are eligible for their
    preferential treatment, this would open new markets for European banks selling covered
    bonds outside the EU. As the experience with the introduction of LCR favourable treatment in
    2015 suggests, the fact itself of granting preferential treatment may foster an increase in
    investments of significant size88
    . Finally, the new EU covered bond framework may represent
    a benchmark at global level, providing third country regulators with a blueprint to further
    develop their own legal frameworks. All these elements could contribute to the achievement
    of a significant portion of the benchmark of 16.5% of third countries investments in EU
    covered bond markets. This could translate into up to €115 billion of additional investments in
    EU covered bond markets coming from outside the EU on a long term multi annual horizon.
    GO2 - Specific objective 1: a legal harmonization along the lines of the EBA report would be
    beneficial in terms of an improved coherence between covered bond structural characteristics
    and covered bond preferential treatment at EU level. This would solve concerns on the
    alignment between the structural characteristics of the product and the preferential treatment.
    Moreover, this coherence would strengthen the international credibility of EU covered bonds
    regime. This would be particularly beneficial for well-established markets which make
    significant use of the preferential provisions in EU legislation.
    GO2 - Specific objective 2: Eligibility conditions for CRR preferential treatment would be
    strengthened. Strengthening the credit characteristics of the instrument will provide benefits
    for investors, but it would also translate into additional costs for issuers. While costs and
    benefits for the two categories may cancel each other out, the final outcome of a more stable
    and financially sound market for covered bonds and the resulting financial stability of funding
    for EU banks translate into a net gain of welfare for the society at large.
    GO2 - Specific objective 3: some rules would be introduced to define principles that must be
    respected in order for a soft bullet/CPT covered bond to be recognized compliant with the
    European definition of covered bond as envisaged in the directive. This would guarantee
    coherence between the new features and the preferential treatment granted to all covered
    bonds, including soft bullets and CPT. At the same time, liquidity requirements would be
    introduced in the directive, while implementing details would be left to Member States. As
    the extendible maturity structures (soft bullets and CPT) affect the extent of liquidity risk,
    Member States could choose to use those structures as partial substitutes of liquidity buffers.
    This could result in a situation where issuers would have the option to choose between
    adopting extensible maturity structures and applying a liquidity buffer to the cover pool. This
    choice could reasonably trigger a conversion of a share of hard bullets into extendible
    maturity structures. Even if it could be reasonably expected that this conversion would happen
    in those countries where liquidity requirements are currently not in place89
    , an estimate of the
    share of the conversion is difficult to predict. The change in structures may not have a major
    impact in terms of pricing, as currently the hard/soft bullet distinction does not represent a
    strong driver of prices90
    . Indeed, the one-off cost of converting such bonds for issuers was
    87
    For example, the lower correlation of non-EU covered bonds to an existing portfolio of EU issued covered
    bonds is an important contribution to stability, in particular for bank treasury investors.
    88
    The 18% increase in issuance between the years 2014 and 2015 is partly due to the entry into force of the
    LCR requirements the same year.
    89
    Countries where a liquidity requirement rule is in place are 9: Belgium, Cyprus, Denmark, France,
    Germany, the Netherlands, Poland, Romania and Slovenia.
    90
    ICF (2017), pp. 101-103; EMF and ECBC, 2017, Market Insights & Updates, February 2017, p. 6
    56
    reported at 0.05 per cent (the standard fee paid recently by several covered bond issuers when
    requesting bondholder consent for such a conversion), while the spreads on covered bonds
    with extendible structures do not appear as systematically different from hard bullet structures
    in the current context. The main costs in terms of increased risks would concern investors, as
    this shift of issuance towards the new liquidity structures would imply a significant shift of
    the liquidity risk from the issuer to the investor. One cannot exclude therefore that the yield
    differentials on covered bonds with extendible structures could become more material in
    times of systemic stress.
    Having a definition in place at EU level for the new structures and setting out principles for
    how to manage the interaction between liquidity buffers and extendible structures would be
    important for keeping risks under control.
    Indirect benefits
    In terms of overall savings in funding costs for the real economy, a significant portion
    (between 50% and 75%) of the benchmark of between €1.5 bn and €1.9 is expected to be
    achieved under this scenario.
    Another indirect benefit of introducing a covered bond legislative framework could be a
    reduction in pro-cyclicality in bank funding. This reduction would be the result of conflicting
    forces. There are some characteristics of covered bonds that go in the direction of increasing
    pro-cyclicality:
     In good times, covered bonds could contribute to feed the demand for real estate and
    through this channel to inflate real estate bubbles. For example, right now in Canada the
    booming real estate is also sustained thanks to covered bonds which, since their
    introduction, have contributed to finance an increased share of the mortgage market;
     Requirements of minimum over collateralisation are pro-cyclical. In scenarios of declines
    in property prices, the sources available to fund over collateralisation may prove
    inadequate. If over collateralization is mandatory to maintain the covered bond label,
    increasing pressure to add collateral to the cover pool may contribute to decreasing banks'
    lending capacity.
    However, especially in adverse market scenarios, covered bonds still show less pro-cyclical
    features than alternative funding sources:
     Values of the assets in the cover pool are not marked to their market value on a regular
    basis. Mortgage cover pools backing covered bonds are only ‘marked to market’ to the
    extent that a house price depreciation causes a deterioration in LTV ratios. LTV ratios are
    the only link through which a decline in real estate prices can affect the cover pool. Only in
    this case, banks would be required to substitute assets in the cover pool;
     As illustrated during and after the financial crisis, covered bonds proved to be a less pro-
    cyclical source of funding for banks than unsecured debt. Covered bonds proved to be
    relatively price stable whereas the volatility of senior unsecured debt issued by financial
    institutions has been much higher. While unsecured lending completely dried up, covered
    bond markets remained open for business.
    Under option 2, LTV limits and overcollateralization requirements (the main pro-cyclical
    components of covered bonds) will only be envisaged for eligibility criteria under CRR art
    129, while no LTV limit or overcollateralization requirement would be envisaged in the
    57
    directive, in line with the EBA advice. In this way, in times of stress and of declining real
    estate prices, the worst consequence could be the loss of the eligibility for the capital
    preferential treatment. However, the instrument would remain in the realm of the general
    covered bond definition as a fall out option, limiting negative consequences for banks and
    pro-cyclicality effects.
    Overall, under option 2, the aspects of counter cyclicality would prevail and this would
    translate into an indirect benefit.
    5.3.2. Costs
    Direct costs
    Under option 2, it would be reasonable to expect that costs increase more significantly than
    under option 1. Adaptation costs may arise from:
     Existing bonds and programmes would need to be grandfathered. However, new rules
    would likely, in most cases, be accommodated within existing covered bond programmes.
    Largest markets with largest issuances would reasonably minimize changes to existing
    programmes in their national legislation. In addition, most of the amendments foreseen
    under this option would increase bond holder protection and, therefore, can be expected to
    obtain their consent (where this is needed) or can be changed without causing controversy.
    Therefore, we wouldn’t expect these costs be significant, apart for some exceptions (see
    below the case of Spain);
     One-off costs for issuers to manage the transition to the new set of rules. These would take
    the form of administrative costs for implementing the changes, for example as a result of
    changing legal documentation or amending IT systems or requiring additional legal advice
    or credit rating valuations. It is likely, that these one-off costs would be higher in those
    countries which currently enjoy lower upfront costs, as they would have to align with a
    new system more similar to the high-cost model. For example, according to market
    stakeholders, potential one-off costs to adapt IT systems to meet the new EU level
    transparency requirements would range between zero and €500,00091
    depending on the
    jurisdiction.
    One-off direct costs for setting up a covered bond programme would then be expected to
    converge towards the range of between €590,000 and €1.8 million (see benchmark). It could
    be estimated that countries with lower direct one-off costs will move in the direction of high-
    cost countries as under option 2 there will be a convergence towards the strongest credit
    characteristics of the most developed and high-cost markets. At the same time, high-costs
    jurisdictions are not expected to decrease their one-off costs.
    Recurring direct costs would be expected to converge towards the range of between €300,000
    and €475,000 per jurisdiction. They might result from increased audit and management fees,
    payment of a fee to a cover pool monitor which did not exist before, other supervisory and
    regulatory new costs. These costs would presumably be higher wherever these features are not
    currently envisaged. For example, recurring costs would increase in countries where cover
    pool monitors are currently not required. In Finland, there is currently no requirement for a
    91
    ICF, 2017, p.127 based on a survey of 67 stakeholders (mainly issuers) carried out in February 2017.
    58
    cover pool monitor and its introduction could cost up until €576,000 per year92
    . In general,
    even when the cover pool monitor is required, new rules enhancing his competences and
    duties could on average increase his costs by 10-20% which would translate into incremental
    recurring costs ranging between €2.4 and €4.8 million across the EU93
    . Another example is
    provided by supervisory and regulatory costs which would likely increase in those Member
    States where supervision is currently following a "light touch" approach. In those countries,
    increasing costs for supervision would be likely paid by issuers. For example, in Austria, the
    Czech Republic and Italy, the introduction of programme licensing arrangements could cost
    issuers up to €1 million.94
    Direct costs are not expected to increase for issuers as a consequence of introducing the EU
    label for covered bonds. As explained in section 4.3, issuers would be able to (voluntarily) use
    this label when marketing their bonds, provided that the product complies with the
    requirements set out in the directive. As no additional labelling process or monitoring of
    compliance is envisaged, extra direct administrative costs are not expected to arise for issuers.
    Spain would be the most affected EU country. Under option 2, the Spanish covered bond law
    would need to undergo substantial changes, particularly concerning the establishment of a
    cover pool, the segregation of the cover assets and new transparency requirements. There are
    two particular features of the current Spanish law that are problematic in relation to the
    objective of minimizing transition costs:
     Covered bond holders have a claim over the entirety of the eligible assets held by the bank.
    A new law establishing a cover register would directly contradict this in that it takes assets
    away from the existing covered bond investors;
     The statutory over-collateralisation is exceptionally high (25 per cent for mortgage covered
    bonds). Under option 2, this number would likely be reduced but this would be detrimental
    to existing bondholders. Any enforced change that could be seen to be detrimental to bond
    holders would generate potentially substantial legal issues and increase grandfathering
    costs.
    Any transition arrangements in Spain are further complicated by the very high number of
    bonds outstanding, the high number of programmes (40), their diverse formats and the fact
    that the last final maturity of a bond issued under the current law is 2046. Moreover, Spanish
    banks are more reliant on covered bond funding than other countries' banks. However, costs
    come with benefits as well. The new features envisaged under the directive would be credit
    positive for Spanish covered bonds and this would help lowering their interest rates and the
    required level of overcollateralization by credit rating agencies (currently rating agencies ask
    up to 157% of overcollateralization for Spanish covered bonds to compensate for the
    perceived weaknesses in their regulatory framework). Another positive element would be the
    implementation of a soft LTV limit which could replace the current hard LTV limit and would
    therefore allow Spanish banks to increase the pool of eligible assets and to issue more covered
    bonds. Finally, clarifying the final outcome of the process would help stakeholders manage
    the transition smoothly. Until now the Spanish Treasury carried out consultations on potential
    92
    Nine programmes multiplied by the European average cost of a cover pool monitor of €64,000. Source: ICF,
    2017, p. 112. However, cover pool monitor tasks could be attributed to the competent authority. In this case,
    costs would be borne by the supervisor.
    93
    In 2015, there were 371 covered bond programmes in EU Member States. Source: ICF, 2017, p.112.
    94
    ICF, 2017, p.115. €13,000 average licencing costs across EU multiplied by the 79 programmes existing in
    the mentioned countries.
    59
    changes on the legal framework without reaching any clear conclusion and this prolonged
    uncertainty is starting to negatively affect the market.
    While costs are expected to increase for issuers under option 2, the same does not apply to
    investors. The credit enhancing features of rules foreseen under option 2 would, on the
    contrary, lower due diligence costs for investors and turn into a benefit for them.
    Enforcement costs
    Supervisory costs borne by public authorities as a result of monitoring activities would change
    compared to the baseline especially for those Member States where supervision is currently
    following a light touch approach. In five EU jurisdictions (Austria, Cyprus, the Czech
    Republic, Italy and Slovakia) the system of supervision does not match the requirements that
    a new EU law would define under option 2. In Austria, the Czech Republic, Italy and
    Slovakia covered bond programmes do not need to be approved, in Austria the framework
    does not set out the supervisor’s duties and powers, in Cyprus the supervisor does not have to
    review operational practices as part of the approval process. In all those Member States,
    specific audits on the cover pool are not part of the supervisor's duties and tasks. Adapting the
    current supervisory system to the enhanced duties and powers that the new framework would
    envisage for supervisors under option 2, would imply increasing costs for light touch
    jurisdictions to converge towards the benchmark. However, those jurisdictions are not
    expected to fully reach the benchmark under option 2 as Member States would likely use their
    space of manoeuvre envisaged under this option to minimize the increase in enforcement
    costs. To what extent benchmark costs will materialize will depend on the choices exercised
    by each Member State.
    Direct costs are not expected to increase for supervisors as a consequence of introducing the
    EU label for covered bonds. As explained in section 4.3, supervisors would be expected to
    monitor compliance with the conditions under which such label could be legally used as part
    of the special public supervision of the covered bond framework. An ex-ante control of the
    use of the label would not be necessary and the costs related to the monitoring of the label
    would be part of the enforcement costs discussed above.
    Indirect costs
    Introducing or amending covered bond legislation could have indirect costs for unsecured
    creditors. This type of impact can be considered under two different angles: the legal and the
    economic one. Under the legal perspective, the concept of dual recourse would require
    Member States to acknowledge in their insolvency legislation the priority of the covered bond
    holder on the cover pool and his pari passu claim (vis-a-vis unsecured creditors) on the
    insolvency estate of the issuer. Two situations may arise:
    – In those Member States where covered bond legislation is in place, national insolvency law
    has already been amended to implement the dual recourse principle. Indeed, this principle
    is the only one complied with by all Member States according to the EBA assessment of
    best practices. According to the EBA Report 2014, a majority of EU jurisdictions have
    introduced bankruptcy provisions that are specific to the event of default of the covered
    bond issuer. Only Bulgaria, Finland and the Netherlands do not have any covered bonds-
    specific insolvency provisions embedded in their legal frameworks. In Germany and
    Denmark, national rules regarding insolvency require that after bondholders are fulfilled by
    the cover pool, the remaining collateral is transferred to the issuer's general insolvency
    estate to serve unsecured creditors;
    60
    – A slightly different situation may characterize those countries where currently there is no
    covered bond legislation in place. This situation would need some specific amendments to
    the insolvency law to accommodate the introduction of covered bonds and the related dual
    recourse principle.
    Overall, the legal impact of the introduction of the directive on unsecured creditors and on
    national insolvency law should be very limited and the current status and ranking of
    unsecured creditors is not expected to worsen significantly in case of insolvency.
    Another aspect of the same problem is of economic nature and regards the fact that a credit
    institution increasing its issuance of covered bonds can affect unsecured creditors through the
    increased level of asset encumbrance. It has been argued that an increase in the number of
    covered bonds issued has potentially adverse effects on the stability of the banking system as
    it reduces the assets available for unsecured bond holders and other creditors. This could lead
    to a lower credit rating on the unsecured bonds, a higher yield demanded by unsecured
    investors and, in extreme scenarios, more difficulties in refinancing maturing debt.95
    In response to this concern and following a specific request by the ESRB, since 2015 the EBA
    has begun to collect data that allow an assessment of the actual encumbrance levels and
    sources in the EEA banking system.96
    According to the EBA, encumbered assets relative to
    total assets was 26.6% in December 2016.97
    This represents a one percentage point increase
    compared with 2015, where the asset encumbrance ratio was 25.4%. The corresponding value
    for December 2014 was 25.1%. This modest uptick in the level of total asset encumbrance in
    2016 is not a cause of concern according to the EBA.
    Nevertheless, large and established covered bond markets (most notably Denmark and
    Sweden) show a high level of asset encumbrance. However, there are some qualifications:
     Covered bonds do not represent the main source of asset encumbrance. Repos represent the
    single most important source of encumbrance at 27%, while covered bonds represent 21%;
     The implications of the encumbrance level depend upon specific features of the domestic
    financial market and the business models of the credit institutions. The high level of
    encumbrance in the Danish financial system is a function of the dominance of specialised
    mortgage lenders who are wholly reliant on covered bond funding. As market indicators
    show, the relatively high encumbrance in Denmark compared to some other Member
    States is not reflected by a higher risk premium demanded by investors; and
     According to the ECBC, covered bond encumbrance tends to be less pro-cyclical in times
    of turmoil than other forms of encumbrance.98
    For example, collateral posted under repos
    is typically marked to its market value on a regular basis, whereas mortgage backing
    covered bonds are only ‘marked to market’ to the extent that a house price depreciation
    causes a deterioration in LTV ratios, thus covered bonds are far less volatile and less pro-
    cyclical in an adverse market scenario.
    While an EU framework is expected to increase the use of covered bonds, and hence use of
    encumbered collateral, there are features of the framework that could mitigate concerns
    95
    Deutsche Bundesbank 2016).
    96
    Data provided regularly by a sample of 196 banks from 29 EEA countries. The sample covers at least 3
    banks from each country including all large ones.
    97
    EBA (2017b).
    98
    ECBC Position Paper on Asset Encumbrance, June 2013
    61
    related to asset encumbrance. For example, some of the requirements envisaged in the new
    framework should contribute to reduce over-collateralisation levels and therefore the level of
    asset encumbrance in the EU banking system. This would affect the statutory requirements of
    OC in national legal frameworks. Currently, they vary between 0 per cent and 25 per cent
    across Member States99
    . The most frequently used values are 2 per cent (typically because this
    is the required over-collateralisation for exemption from clearing obligations for associated
    derivatives under EMIR) and 5 per cent. 12 Member States have OC statutory levels higher
    than 2% and 5 Member States have statutory requirements higher than 5%. As under option 2
    the EU framework would require a minimum statutory OC level of between 2% and 5%
    depending on the quality of the assets in the cover pool, this could potentially contribute to
    lower OC levels across the EU100
    . Furthermore, credit rating agencies may have an impact.
    Over-collateralisation levels required by rating agencies are typically high, especially where
    national covered bond frameworks are considered weaker in terms of investor protection.
    Requirements by credit rating agencies could reach 100% or even 150% of
    overcollateralization in those jurisdictions considered weaker by investors101
    . Strengthening
    investor protection across the EU might contribute to induce rating agencies to lower their OC
    requirements thus reducing aggregate encumbrance levels in the banking system for any given
    quantity of covered bonds outstanding.
    Securitization is not dissimilar from covered bonds in terms of effects on unsecured creditors.
    In both cases, exposures underlying the securitisation and the covered bond are not available
    to unsecured creditors and are reserved to investors in the securitisation/covered bond. Using
    these methods of funding do remove assets that otherwise would have been available to fulfil
    unsecured creditors. This is the risk of being unsecured which is also reflected in the pricing
    of unsecured debt compared to secured one.
    5.3.3. Overall assessment
    Effectiveness, efficiency, coherence
    Overall option 2 is considered to achieve most of the objectives of the initiative at reasonable
    costs by combining enough flexibility to accommodate Member States features with the
    objective of achieving coherence at EU level for covered bonds. This option would have the
    best chance of being effective in achieving stated objective, while at the same time being
    efficient, minimizing disruption and transition costs. Of the options considered, it therefore
    represents the most efficient and effective way to address the problems envisaged in section 2.
    Winners and losers
    On the basis of the above, table 7 summarises the benefits and costs of option 2 for each
    category of stakeholders. Issuers would benefit from a lowering of funding costs and citizens
    would enjoy in their turn some lower borrowing costs as well. Investors would benefit from a
    stronger regime, however some details left to Member States’ discretion could introduce
    weaknesses (for example in the relationship between extendible structures and liquidity
    buffer). Costs would increase for issuers and supervisors, while they would decrease for
    investors and society.
    99
    In Spain, for example, the minimum regulatory OC is currently 25 per cent, or circa €70 billion.
    100
    It is worth noting, however, that there is no intention to impose a constraint on national regulators wanting
    to set a higher level than the EU minimum. It is also worth noting that there is nothing to stop issuers setting
    higher levels of OC to preserve credit ratings or investor confidence.
    101
    In Spain, credit rating agencies might ask up to 157% of overcollateralization to issuers.
    62
    Table 7 – Impacts on different stakeholders of Option 2
    Issuers Investors Supervisors Citizens
    Benefits
    ↑↑ ↑ ↑
    ↑↑
    Costs
    ↑↑ ↓ ↑ ↓
    Stakeholder views
    Option 2 is favoured by a large majority of stakeholders: institutional, supervisors, Member
    States and industry. The EBA, the ECB, the Parliament, national and European supervisors
    favour this option. This is the option that fits with the EBA Report and the EP Report. A
    majority of Member States is also favourable to this option, including all those with the
    largest markets. In particular, Member States with the two largest and well-established
    markets such as DE and DK are favourable to this option as they see in the legislative
    harmonization the opportunity to extend the soundness and stability that characterize their
    markets to the rest of the EU. France and Sweden were initially the most sceptical and were
    more in favour of option 1, but they eventually converged on this option after the publication
    of the EBA Report. Italy and Spain would suffer the most significant increases in costs among
    the largest markets. In spite of this, however, both countries support option 2. Spain, for
    example, is aware of the need to change the current covered bond framework and has carried
    out several consultations without reaching clear conclusions. The EU initiative is seen as an
    opportunity to provide clear guidance on the way forward and start delivering a long-awaited
    change.
    Industry is split between those who would prefer option 1 and those who would prefer option
    2, while no support at all is given to options 3 and 4. The ECBC representing almost all
    issuers in the market and investors is clearly in favour of option 2. According to a survey
    conducted by ICF in February 2017 on a sample of 65 stakeholders (mainly issuers)102
    , a
    harmonised legislative framework for covered bonds at EU level along the lines of option 2
    would deliver the following benefits (in percentage the number of respondents agreeing):
     Reduce regulatory fragmentation (74 per cent);
     facilitate reduction in asset and liability mismatches (68 per cent);
     improve ease and quality of due diligence and credit analysis of covered bonds (lower
    barriers to invest) (60 per cent);
     facilitate developments of CB framework in all the 28 EU countries in line with CMU
    agenda (60 per cent);
     improve the efficiency of monetary policy transmission (higher availability of high quality
    collateral) (60 per cent)
     facilitate capital market access to small-medium issuers (58 per cent);
     reduce investors' reliance on external ratings (54 per cent).
    5.4. Option 3 – Full harmonization
    This option would involve the design of a new fully harmonized regime for covered bonds. In
    doing so, it would need to define every detail of a sound covered bond regulatory framework
    102
    ICF, 2017, pp. 50-51
    63
    and would not thus follow a principle based approach. The legislative instrument envisaged to
    implement this option would be a regulation.
    5.4.1. Benefits
    Direct benefits
    GO1 - Specific objective 1: as this option would entail a regulation to define covered bonds
    rather than a directive, it would be directly applicable to all Member States without having to
    wait for them implementing the directive and without bearing monitoring and implementation
    costs. Any risk of non-compliance with the directive would be eliminated. The full benchmark
    benefit in terms of number of countries with a covered bond framework in place would be
    achieved immediately at the entering into force of the regulation. It is reasonable to expect
    that once a compelling regulation is in place across the EU, this would stimulate the
    development of covered bond markets also in countries where currently they don't exist yet
    (see explanation provided in option 2). The benchmark in terms of additional amount of
    covered bond issuance is expected to be almost fully achieved (between 75% and 100% of the
    maximum long-term benefit). Increasing the share of covered bond issuance vs unsecured
    debt, would help banks to lower the cost of their funding achieving most of the benchmark
    (between 75% and 100% of the maximum benefit). The impact of an EU regulation would not
    only be felt in less developed markets, but also in well-functioning ones. Among the latter, a
    direct benefit that could stem from the EU regulation would be the improvement in the credit
    characteristics of the instrument that would lead to higher credit ratings and, therefore, to
    lower financing costs for issuers (with benefits of €1.1bn of yearly savings in line with
    calculations in benchmark c).
    Expanding the scope of covered bond markets is not only to be intended from the
    geographical perspective, but also in terms of issuers' characteristics. The new regulation
    would introduce measures to allow the use of pooled covered bond structures and encourage
    the issuance by smaller banks.
    GO1 - Specific objective 2: investor base diversification in line with the benchmark of 60%,
    could be reasonably achieved not only as an indirect consequence of the tapering of the ECB
    purchasing programmes as suggested in the baseline. Introducing mandatory strengthened
    requirements and more transparency for covered bonds would make the product safer and
    more attractive for more risk adverse investors such as asset managers, insurers and pension
    funds. At the same time, a full harmonization of the market would make the product more
    easily understandable and more liquid, attracting further all types of investors,
    GO1 - Specific objective 3: the fact that there would be no discretionary space for Member
    States to interpret and implement norms to suit their specificities, would make the system
    more homogenous and better integrated and this should foster further cross border
    investments. The 73% benchmark could be expected to be hit. In terms of cross-border cover
    pools similar considerations hold as under option 2.
    GO1 - Specific objective 4: full harmonization provided through a regulation would favour
    investments from third countries, would foster the possibility to establish an equivalence
    reciprocal regime and will also provide all jurisdictions in the world with a law text
    representing a benchmark at global level. All these elements would contribute to the
    achievement of the benchmark of 16.5% of third countries investments in EU covered bond
    64
    markets. This would translate into up to €115 billion of additional investments in EU covered
    bond markets coming from outside the EU on a long term multi-year horizon.
    GO2 - Specific objective 1: a full harmonization along the lines of the EBA report, only more
    detailed, would be beneficial in terms of coherence between covered bond structural
    characteristics and covered bond preferential treatment at EU level. There would be no
    discretionary space for Member States to interpret and implement norms to suit their
    specificities and this would better guarantee full coherence between covered bonds structural
    characteristics and their preferential prudential treatment at EU level. Moreover, under this
    option, one could envisage the SSM also conducting the special supervision of covered bonds
    for the largest banks issuing covered bonds in the euro area. This would further strengthen
    homogeneity in the way rules are applied and enforced. Benefits of comprehensive
    harmonization would therefore fully be achieved with less risks of divergence than under
    option 2. Moreover, this coherence would strengthen the international credibility of EU
    covered bonds regime. This would be particularly beneficial for well-established markets
    which make significant use of the preferential provisions in EU legislation.
    GO2 - Specific objective 2: Eligibility conditions for CRR preferential treatment would be
    strengthened in a way similar to option 2. While strengthening the credit characteristics of the
    instrument will provide benefits for investors, it would also translate into additional costs for
    issuers. While costs and benefits for the two categories may cancel each other out, the final
    outcome of a more stable and financially sound market for covered bonds and the resulting
    prudentially sounder funding for EU banks translate into a net gain of welfare for the society
    at large.
    GO2 - Specific objective 3: rules would be introduced to define principles that must be
    respected in order for a soft bullet/CPT covered bond to be recognized compliant with the
    European definition of covered bond in the regulation. This would guarantee coherence
    between the new features and the preferential treatment granted to all covered bonds,
    including soft bullets and CPT. In addition, as the extendible maturity structures (soft bullets
    and CPT) affect the extent of liquidity risk, the regulation would define strict rules for how to
    manage the interaction between liquidity buffers and extendible structures instead of leaving
    this choice to Member States in order to keep risks under control.
    Indirect benefits
    In terms of overall savings in funding costs for the real economy, most of the benchmark of
    between €1.5 bn and €1.9 (between 75% and 100% of the maximum benefit) could be
    expected to be achieved under this option.
    Concerning the indirect effects in terms of pro-cyclicality, similar considerations hold as for
    option 2. Also under option 3, those features of covered bonds which favour pro-cyclicality
    such as LTV limits and overcollateralization requirements would only be envisaged for
    eligibility criteria under CRR art 129, and excluded from the directive. In this way, in times of
    stress and of declining real estate prices, the worst consequence could be the loss of the
    eligibility for the capital preferential treatment. However, the instrument would remain in the
    realm of the general covered bond definition as a fall out option, limiting negative
    consequences for banks and pro-cyclicality effects. Overall, under option 3, the aspects of
    counter cyclicality would prevail and this would translate into an indirect benefit.
    65
    5.4.2. Costs
    Direct costs
    Under option 3, it would be reasonable to expect higher costs than under option 2, especially
    in terms of one-off adaptation costs. Option 3 would indeed impose a one-size fits all
    approach which would imply more significant changes in every jurisdiction than under option
    2. Instead of a principle based approach which could be adapted to different national
    circumstances, detailed rules will need to be specified under option 3 and this would also
    entail a significant amount of level 2 legislation. The major impacts will be in terms of one-
    off and transition costs:
     Existing bonds and programmes would need to be grandfathered. While under option 2 it
    could be expected that national legislators would aim at minimizing transition costs, a
    regulation introducing more radical changes compared to the status quo would increase
    significantly the costs of the transition and adaptation of the current programmes;
     One-off costs for issuers to manage the transition to the new set of rules. These would take
    the form of administrative costs for implementing the changes, for example as a result of
    changing legal documentation or amending IT systems or requiring additional legal advice
    or credit rating valuations. These costs would presumably be higher than under option 2 as
    no national adaptation would be possible. For example, considering that market
    stakeholders estimated potential one-off costs to adapt IT systems to meet the new EU
    level transparency requirements would range between zero and €500,000103
    , it is likely that
    under option 3 costs would be at the upper end of the range.
    One-off direct costs for setting up a covered bond programme are then expected to converge
    towards the upper bound of the range provided in the benchmark of €1.8 million. It could be
    estimated that countries with lower direct one-off costs will move in the direction of high-cost
    countries as under option 3 there will be convergence towards the strongest credit
    characteristics of the most developed and high-cost markets. At the same time, high-costs
    jurisdictions are not expected to decrease their one-off costs.
    Recurring direct costs are expected to converge towards the range of between €300,000 and
    €475,000 per jurisdiction. They might result from increased audit and management fees,
    payment of a fee to a cover pool monitor which did not exist before, other supervisory and
    regulatory new costs. These costs would presumably be higher wherever these features are not
    currently envisaged. Similar examples hold as for option 2. Similar considerations as under
    option 2 are also valid for the case of Spain.
    While costs are expected to sensibly increase for issuers under option 3, the same does not
    apply to investors. The credit enhancing features of rules foreseen under option 3 would, on
    the contrary, lower due diligence costs for investors and turn into a benefit for them.
    For labelling costs, similar considerations hold as for option 2.
    Enforcement costs
    Supervisory costs would increase compared to the baseline especially for those Member
    States where supervision is currently following a light touch approach. Adapting the current
    supervisory system to the enhanced duties and powers that the new regulation would envisage
    103
    ICF, 2017, p.127 based on a survey of 67 stakeholders (mainly issuers) carried out in February 2017.
    66
    for supervisors under option 3, would imply higher costs for light touch jurisdictions which
    would reach the benchmark. Similar considerations and examples hold as for option 2.
    However, some additional costs would arise under option 3 compared to option 2. First of all,
    a major effort in terms of issuance of level 2 legislation by EU bodies would be needed to
    allow a new detailed framework be fully up and running across the EU. Secondly, under this
    option a centralized supervision under the SSM could be envisaged for the largest banks
    issuing covered bonds in the euro area. The shift of supervision from national authorities to
    the SSM would imply adaptation and organizational costs. Resulting costs would be borne
    both by the SSM and the national authorities. For labelling costs, similar considerations hold
    as for option 2. Overall, enforcement costs are expected to fully hit the benchmark.
    Indirect costs
    Introducing or amending covered bond legislation could have indirect costs for unsecured
    creditors. This type of impact can be considered under two different angles: the legal and the
    economic one. Under both perspectives, similar considerations hold as for option 2, including
    the estimates of asset encumbrance.
    Option 3 would also present further indirect costs in terms of disruption of well- functioning
    existing national markets. The one-size-fits-all approach implicit in option 3 could indeed
    hamper the functioning of several EU jurisdictions and could potentially undermine well-
    functioning national regimes and markets. In countries where covered bond markets play a
    fundamental role in the respective economies, disruption in covered bond markets could
    potentially hamper the overall economy and financial stability of those countries. Quantifying
    the costs of such a disruption is not possible with the data available.
    5.4.3. Overall assessment
    Effectiveness, efficiency, coherence
    On the whole, this option would achieve the objectives of the initiative. A new covered bond
    regime along the lines of this option would constitute an integrated and coherent framework
    for covered bond markets compared to the status quo. As this framework would include
    detailed proposals for every aspect of covered bond operations, there is no risk that Member
    States might not implement uniformly the rules defined in EU law. However, detailed
    harmonisation could have unintended negative consequences, especially for well-functioning
    markets, neutralising possible benefits. This option would be less efficient than option 2 as
    transition costs would be higher and it would risk damaging those markets already working
    well, with unpredictable and difficult to estimate consequences. While benefits might turn out
    to be higher in the long term, the costs in the short to medium term would be
    disproportionately high. Therefore, whereas the option would guarantee effectiveness and
    coherence, it would do so at high costs.
    Winners and losers
    On the basis of the above, table 8 summarises the benefits and costs of option 3 for each
    category of stakeholders. Issuers would benefit from a lowering of funding costs and citizens
    would enjoy in their turn some lower borrowing costs as well. Investors would benefit from a
    stronger regime, while supervisors would suffer from losing some of their competences in
    favour of the ECB. Costs would increase for issuers and supervisors up to the maximum
    extent of the benchmark, while they would decrease for investors. Overall, costs would
    increase for citizens because of the risk of disruption of well-functioning markets.
    67
    Table 8 – Impacts on different stakeholders of Option 3
    Issuers Investors Supervisors Citizens
    Benefits
    ↑↑ ↑↑ ↓
    ↑↑
    Costs
    ↑↑ ↓ ↑↑ ↑↑
    Stakeholder views
    A large majority of stakeholders have suggested discarding this option. Among them
    institutional stakeholders, supervisors, Member States and industry stakeholders. The EBA
    and the Parliament discarded this option as well. The totality of Member States opposes it, in
    particular Member States with well-established markets. All the largest markets indeed
    oppose this option (DE, DK, FR, ES, SE, IT).
    According to a survey conducted by ICF in February 2017 on a sample of 65 stakeholders
    (mainly issuers)104
    , 88 per cent of the respondents think that the main risk of introducing a
    covered bond framework at EU level would be the disruption of well-functioning national
    regimes and markets.
    5.5. Option 4 – 29th
    parallel regime
    2. This option would be similar to option 3 with the difference that instead of substituting
    the current 28 regimes with a new one as envisaged in option 3, the newly created regime
    would operate in parallel and compete with the existing 28 ones, becoming the 29th
    regime.
    Differently from option 3, the new regime, if successful, could be expected to gradually
    replace the existing ones instead of directly superseding them from the outset. This
    replacement would happen on the basis of voluntary adoption by actors in the market. Two
    sub-options should be assessed105
    . Sub-option 4.1: the system is neutral with no specific
    incentives for issuers/investors to embrace the 29th
    regime. Even if very well crafted in
    compliance with all the EBA best practices, there is no reason to expect this regime will take
    off in well established markets which will likely continue using their current systems and
    labels. Smaller countries without large and well-established markets would instead likely
    adopt the new regime. Sub-option 4.2: to make the 29th
    regime attractive relative to
    established instruments, another option is to grant it a more favourable preferential prudential
    treatment. This has also been recognized by respondents to the public consultation. However,
    given that further strengthening the preferential regime of certain covered bonds would not be
    politically acceptable, granting more favourable prudential treatment to the 29th
    regime
    effectively means repealing or reducing the preferential treatment of the existing regimes.
    5.5.1. Benefits
    Direct benefits
    GO1 - Specific objective 1: as this option would entail a regulation to define covered bonds
    rather than a directive, it would be directly applicable to all Member States without having to
    wait for them implementing the directive and without bearing monitoring and implementation
    costs. Any risk of non-compliance with the directive would be eliminated. The full benchmark
    104
    ICF, 2017, pp. 52-54.
    105
    Estimated benefits and costs are normally to be intended for the general option, unless otherwise specified.
    68
    benefit in terms of number of countries with a covered bond framework in place would be
    achieved immediately at the entering into force of the regulation. However, differently than
    under option 3, Member States would be allowed to retain existing national systems. It is
    reasonable to expect that also under option 4, once a compelling regulation is in place across
    the EU, this would stimulate the development of covered bond markets, especially in
    countries where currently they do not yet exist (see option 2). The benchmark in terms of
    additional amount of covered bond issuance is expected to be only partially achieved if no
    incentives are put in place as under sub-option 4.1 (25% of the benchmark). The main impact
    in terms of increased issuance would likely be felt on less developed markets. Increasing the
    share of covered bond issuance would help banks to lower the cost of their funding. However,
    the benchmark would only be partially achieved (25% of the benchmark). Under sub-option
    4.2, incentives in terms of more favourable preferential prudential treatment would be used to
    maximize the take up of the new regime. This could help achieving a higher share of the
    benchmark (50%) both in terms of issuance and related savings. However, this would come at
    high costs of disruption of the existing markets.
    Expanding the scope of covered bond markets is not only to be intended from the
    geographical perspective, but also in terms of issuers' characteristics. The new regulation
    would introduce measures to allow the use of pooled covered bond structures and encourage
    the issuance by smaller banks.
    GO1 - Specific objective 2: investor base diversification in line with the benchmark of 60%
    would not be achieved. What can be achieved is the 50% of the baseline due to the
    consequence of the tapering of the ECB purchasing programme. However, additional benefits
    deriving from a unified market would not materialize as the market would likely remain
    fragmented under this option. Well-established markets are indeed expected to retain their
    current systems and those would co-exist with the 29th
    regime, especially under sub-option
    4.1. Under sub-option 4.2, the disruption in the banking sector due to the repealing or
    reduction of the preferential prudential treatment could favour investor diversification away
    from banks. However, it would come at high costs of disruption among investing banks.
    Some additional benefit can be expected compared to the baseline only under sub-option 4.2.
    GO1 - Specific objective 3: introducing a 29th
    regime would not address the problem of
    market fragmentation. The benchmark benefit is not expected to be achieved.
    GO1 - Specific objective 4: introducing a 29th
    regime would not address the problem of
    market fragmentation and this may not help attracting third country investments. Under sub-
    option 4.2, the new regime could be expected to be successful in taking off and in becoming
    the EU standard for third country investors at least in the long term. Whether this option
    would allow achieving the intended benefits depends crucially on the degree of adoption by
    industry stakeholders which could be estimated low on the basis of the public consultation
    feedback. Overall, the benchmark benefit of 16.5% is not expected to be achieved.
    GO2 - Specific objective 1: under option 4 a regulation instead of a directive would define
    covered bond characteristics. There would be no discretionary space for Member States to
    interpret and implement norms to suit their specificities and this would better guarantee full
    coherence between covered bonds structural characteristics and their preferential prudential
    treatment at EU level. However, under sub-option 4.1, prudential concerns for the existing
    regimes would not be addressed. Only under sub-option 4.2, prudential concerns would be
    addressed. However, this would be costly and would provoke market turmoil. Costs related to
    the potential loss of preferential treatment would arise (see option 1). All those costs are likely
    69
    to offset any potential benefit deriving from this sub-option. The benefits of comprehensive
    harmonization under both sub-options would therefore not be achieved.
    GO2 - Specific objective 2: eligibility conditions for CRR preferential treatment would be
    strengthened in a way similar to options 2 and 3. While this would solve the issue of the
    adequacy of art 129 capital treatment under sub-option 4.1, under sub-option 4.2 the change to
    the CRR would exclusively concern the 29th
    regime. This would significantly diminish its
    importance. It would also be costly and disruptive and would provoke turmoil in existing
    markets. Costs related to the potential loss of preferential treatment would arise (see option 1).
    Benefits of strengthening the capital preferential treatment would therefore only partially be
    achieved under sub-option 4.2.
    GO2 - Specific objective 3: rules would be introduced to define principles that must be
    respected in order for a soft bullet/CPT covered bond to be recognized compliant with the
    European definition of covered bond in the regulation. This would guarantee coherence
    between the new features and the preferential treatment granted to all covered bonds,
    including soft bullets and CPT. In addition, as the extendible maturity structures (soft bullets
    and CPT) affect the extent of liquidity risk, the regulation would define strict rules for how to
    manage the interaction between liquidity buffers and extendible structures instead of leaving
    this choice to Member States in order to keep risks under control. However, those rules will
    be applicable only to those covered bonds issued under the 29th
    regime. Covered bonds
    outside the 29th
    regime would stay under current rules and maybe follow market based
    standards (see baseline). If the latter would not be aligned with the EU rules under the 29th
    regime, this could create confusion in the markets and could translate into higher costs both
    for issuers and for investors. Benefits would therefore only partially be achieved.
    Indirect benefits
    In terms of overall savings in funding costs for the real economy, the benchmark of between
    €1.5 bn and €1.9 is expected to be achieved only partially under this scenario (between 25%
    and 50% of the maximum benefit).
    While in terms of pro-cyclicality a similar approach would be followed under option 4 as
    under options 2 and 3, it is not clear the relevance this might have in financial markets.
    Whether those effects matter at all would depend on the size of the market based on the 29th
    regime which on its turn depends on the degree of adoption by industry stakeholders. The
    latter could be estimated low on the basis of the public consultation feedback.
    5.5.2. Costs
    Direct costs
    The introduction of a 29th
    regime would increase complexity as issuers would have to cope
    with the administrative costs of dealing with an additional regime. These costs would be both
    one-off (changing legal documentation, amending IT systems, requiring additional legal
    advice) and recurrent (increased audit and management fees, payment of a fee to a cover pool
    monitor, other supervisory and regulatory costs). In terms of one-off and transition costs, they
    would be similar to option 3. One-off direct costs for setting up a covered bond programme
    could therefore be expected to move towards the upper bound of the range provided in the
    benchmark of €1.8 million. Recurrent costs are expected to fully hit the benchmark of
    between €300,000 and €475,000.
    70
    Under sub-option 4.1, the likely fragmentation of the market into several regimes including
    the 29th
    would likely cause duplication of costs for those issuers choosing to manage more
    than one regime at the same time. Under sub-option 4.2, it is more likely that systems
    converge; however this would happen only in the long-term and at high costs as current
    regimes and well-established national markets would be disrupted.
    For labelling costs, similar considerations hold as for options 2 and 3.
    An increase in costs compared to the baseline would also be expected for investors, as in their
    due diligence processes instead of simplifying and saving costs, they would have to deal with
    an additional regime implying higher complexity, lower transparency and higher costs (this
    especially holds under sub-option 4.1).
    Enforcement costs
    The introduction of a 29th
    regime would place a further burden on supervisors as they would
    have to deal with an additional regime. This would be the case under sub-option 4.1, while
    under sub-option 4.2 the convergence to a single harmonised regime could take place in the
    long term. In both cases, the transition would imply higher complexity and higher costs for
    supervisors as they would not only have to adapt the current supervisory system to the
    enhanced duties and powers that the new regulation would envisage similarly to what happens
    under option 3. They would also have to supervise an additional regime subject to a different
    set of rules. This could risk duplicating supervisory costs. In addition, a major effort in terms
    of issuance of level 2 legislation by EU bodies would be needed under option 4 to allow a
    new detailed framework be fully up and running across the EU. Finally, under this option a
    centralized supervision under the SSM could be envisaged for the largest banks issuing
    covered bonds in the euro area. The shift of supervision from national authorities to the SSM
    would imply adaptation and organizational costs. For labelling costs, similar considerations
    hold as for options 2 and 3. Overall, the benchmark for enforcement costs is expected to be
    fully hit.
    Indirect costs
    Introducing or amending covered bond legislation could have indirect costs for unsecured
    creditors. This type of impact can be considered under two different angles: the legal and the
    economic one. Under both perspectives, similar considerations hold as for options 2 and 3.
    However, it is not clear the relevance this might have in financial markets. Whether those
    effects matter at all would depend on the size of the market based on the 29th
    regime which on
    its turn depends on the degree of adoption by industry stakeholders. The latter could be
    estimated low on the basis of the public consultation feedback.
    5.5.3. Overall assessment
    Effectiveness, efficiency, coherence
    While a new covered bond regime along the lines of this option would constitute an integrated
    and coherent framework for covered bond markets and would offer a comprehensive
    regulatory framework to issuers wanting to use an EU label, this option would entail either
    low effectiveness or high costs depending on which sub-option is chosen. Under sub-option
    4.1, a limited market take-up is expected, differentiated according to whether covered bond
    markets are already in place (low) or not (high). Therefore its effectiveness in accomplishing
    stated objectives would be undermined. Under sub-option 4.2, the take up could be
    71
    maximized; however, this would come at the cost of disruption of the existing markets.
    Option 4 would increase fragmentation and related costs especially under sub-option 4.1,
    resulting in this option being less efficient. Overall the option would not guarantee the
    achievement of the objectives of the review in an effective, efficient and coherent way. While
    for other EU initiatives a 29th
    regime could be considered the optimal solution, in this case the
    final objective is the convergence to a single harmonized framework, differently than for
    example in the PEPP initiative. Ending up with different frameworks or converging on a
    single one only in the long term and at high costs in terms of disruption, would not be an
    effective and efficient way to achieve the specific objectives of this initiative and to match its
    level of policy ambition.
    Winners and losers
    On the basis of the above, table 9 summarises the benefits and costs of option 4 for each
    category of stakeholders. Issuers would benefit from a lowering of funding costs and citizens
    would enjoy in their turn some lower borrowing costs as well. Investors would benefit from a
    stronger regime only if they invest in covered bonds issued under the 29th
    regime, while
    supervisors would suffer from losing some of their competences in favour of the ECB and for
    having to monitor different regimes. Costs would increase for issuers and supervisors up to
    the maximum extent of the benchmark as the regimes under their management/supervision
    would likely be more than one. Under this option costs would also increase for investors due
    to complexity in the market following the introduction of a 29th
    parallel regime. Overall, costs
    would increase for citizens because of the increased fragmentation under sub-option 4.1 or for
    costs of disruption of the existing markets under sub-option 4.2.
    Table 9 – Impacts on different stakeholders of Option 4
    Issuers Investors Supervisors Citizens
    Benefits
    ↑ ↑ ↓
    ↑
    Costs
    ↑↑ ↑ ↑↑
    ↑
    Stakeholder views
    This option did not find any support amongst stakeholders. Stakeholders from all groups
    (supervisory authorities, Member States, the EBA, investors, issuers and the ECB) pointed to
    increased market fragmentation, lower transparency and more uncertainty as a result of
    introducing a new system in parallel to the existing national systems. Stakeholders also
    noticed that in order to ensure a high take up incentives would need to be provided in terms of
    preferential treatment (sub-option 4.2). However, they expressed concerns about disrupting
    current markets under this sub-option. The EBA did not assess this option in their 2016 report.
    The Parliament did not consider this option in their report either. Member States expressed
    their concern with this option in the course of expert groups meetings.
    6. COMPARISON OF OPTIONS
    Table 10 summarises the extent to which the options are effective, efficient and coherent.
    Effectiveness is mapped against the specific objectives set out in section 3. The respective
    scores are attributed on the basis of the analysis above.
    72
    Table 10 – Summary of options in terms of effectiveness, efficiency and coherence
    Effectiveness Efficiency Coherence Score
    Objective 1
    Enhance
    CMU
    potential
    Objective 2
    Coherence of
    prudential
    regulation with
    characteristics
    of the
    instrument
    Baseline 0 0 0 0 0
    Option 1 + ≈ ++ ≈ 3
    Option 2 ++ + ++ + 6
    Option 3 ++ ++ - - ++ 4
    Option 4 ++ + - + 3
    Magnitude of impact as compared with the baseline scenario: ++ strongly positive (score 2); + positive (score 1); – –
    strongly negative (score -2); – negative (score -1); ≈ marginal/neutral (score 0).
    Table 10 shows that option 1 is not effective in terms of meeting the objectives whereas
    options 2, 3 and 4 do it to a varying extent. At the same time, the table shows that option 2 is
    expected to achieve the objectives at lesser costs compared to options 3 and 4. As regards
    coherence, option 3 scores the best but options 2 and 4 are also judged in line with overall
    policy objectives. In sum, the option which promises the best possible balance across the three
    criteria of effectiveness, efficiency and coherence is option 2.
    Having established how the options score in terms of effectiveness, efficiency and coherence,
    table 11 also highlights how the options score in terms of the level of stakeholder support
    and overall level of regulatory ambition. The latter could be an indication of the political
    challenges associated with the option in question.
    Table 11 – Summary of pros/cons of options
    Option Effectiveness/efficiency/coherence Stakeholders support Level of ambition/challenge
    1 Medium (3) Medium Low
    2 High (6) High Medium
    3 High (4) Low High
    4 Medium (3) Low Medium
    Table 11 shows that options 2 and 3 present the best combination of the criteria of
    effectiveness, efficiency and coherence underlined by their high scores. At the same time,
    stakeholders support is high for option 2, medium for option 1, while it is low for options 3
    and 4. Options 2, 3 and 4 are rated to be more ambitious.
    73
    6.1.1. Retained option
    In light of the above, the retained option is option 2: minimum harmonization based on
    national regimes. It achieves most of the objectives of the initiative at reasonable costs. It
    furthermore appropriately balances the degree of flexibility necessary to accommodate
    Member States features with the uniformity that is necessary for achieving coherence at EU
    level. It is likely to be the most effective in achieving the objectives, while at the same time
    being efficient, minimising disruption and transition costs. Of the options considered, it is
    also, among the most ambitious options in regulatory terms, while, at the same time, being the
    course of action that enjoys the highest support by stakeholders. All of them: institutional
    stakeholders, supervisors, Member States and industry support this option. The EBA, the
    ECB, the Parliament, national and European supervisors have advocated for this option. This
    is the option that fits with the EBA Report and the EP Report. A majority of Member States is
    also favourable to this option. Among them, all the largest markets. The ECBC (representing
    almost all issuers in the market and investors) is also in favour of this option.
    3. Annex 6 describes the detailed provisions under the retained option, specifying for
    each of them whether and how they deviate from the EBA 2016 Report and how they differ
    from the current situation in Member States where a legal covered bond framework is in
    place. The last column in the table in Annex 6 summarizes the potential impacts on Member
    States of the detailed provisions under the retained option.
    7. OTHER SPECIFIC IMPACTS OF THE RETAINED POLICY OPTION
    7.1. Impacts on SMEs
    The policy option chosen would have some direct and indirect positive effects on SME
    financing. Direct benefits stem from the fact that covered bonds sometimes directly finance
    commercial and residential mortgages which are often related to SME activities.
    Entrepreneurs can use their residential property as collateral for financing their professional
    activity; commercial mortgages finance business facilities (offices, productive capacity and
    shopping malls, etc.); public sector loans finance local infrastructure (like schools, hospitals
    etc.) and possibly guarantee SME loans.
    However, the most significant benefit on SMEs would come from the initiative on European
    Secured Note (ESN) which, as explained at the forefront of this impact assessment, is a
    parallel separate initiative.
    7.2. Social impacts
    The main social impacts of the retained option would be on the housing and real estate
    markets. As shown in section 2.1.1, covered bonds are an important tool for financing
    mortgages. Mortgages (around €7 trillion in 2015) represent 16% of total assets in the EU
    banking sector (€43.3 trillion) and 30% of the total loans provided by EU banks (€23.5 trillion
    in 2015). In terms of share of residential lending, covered bonds finance an average of 30% of
    residential mortgages lending in the EU in 2015 (see section 2.1.1.). Fostering covered bond
    markets would contribute to lower interest rates on mortgages (see benchmark for indirect
    benefits).
    74
    7.3. Environmental impacts
    Covered bonds contribute to finance lending and hence increase demand for commercial and
    residential real estate. This contributes to increasing the supply of real estate, which has an
    effect on the environment. To mitigate environmental concerns, the European Mortgage
    Federation/ECBC has launched an “Energy Efficient Mortgage Initiative” to support energy
    efficiency improvements in buildings. The aim of the initiative is to explore ways to mobilise
    private mortgage financing to boost energy efficient building renovation in Europe.
    In the EU, buildings are responsible for 40% of total energy consumption and 36% of CO2
    emissions. About 35% of the EU’s buildings are over 50 years old and 75-90% of the building
    stock is predicted to remain standing in 2050, making energy efficient renovation a top
    priority for Europe. By improving the energy efficiency of buildings alone, the EU’s total
    energy consumption could be reduced by 5-6% and CO2 emissions by 5%. The scale of the
    investment needed is estimated at around €100 billion per year.
    European mortgage and covered bond industries could play a role in the financing of those
    investments in energy efficiency. The idea is to incentivise homeowners to move their
    properties out of the ‘brown’ zone (e.g. energy rating E-G) into the ‘green’ zone (e.g. energy
    rating A-D) by way of preferential interest rates or additional funds at the time of origination
    of the mortgage. Mortgages as an existing financial product are indeed familiar to consumers
    in Europe, and are offered at an important moment in the building lifecycle in terms of the
    opportunity to renovate real estate. An appropriate mortgage instrument could therefore
    contribute to increasing the current rate of energy efficient building renovation. The initiative
    is only recently developing, but it could become material over the medium term with
    significant environmental impacts in terms of energy efficiency.
    EU action by means of minimum harmonisation of covered bonds could lend support to those
    efforts by further developing covered bond markets.
    8. MONITORING AND EVALUATION
    No sooner than five years after the date of transposition of the Directive, the Commission
    shall carry out an evaluation of this legislative package (consisting of a regulation and of a
    directive) and present a Report on the main findings to the European Parliament, the Council
    and the European Economic and Social Committee. The evaluation shall be conducted
    according to the Commission's better regulation Guidelines.
    Member States shall provide the Commission with the information necessary for the
    preparation of that Report.
    Member States shall regularly monitor the application of this legislative package based on the
    following non-exhaustive list of indicators, which correspond to the benchmark benefits and
    costs as defined in section 5.1 and exemplified in table 12.
    Table 12 – Benchmark benefits/costs and related monitoring indicators
    Objective Benchmark benefits Monitoring indicators
    General Objective 1
    Enhance CMU potential
    Specific objective 1: develop
    covered bond markets in all EU
    countries
    a) Number of countries adopting a
    framework
    b) Additional issuance
    1) Number of MS adopting a CB
    framework
    2) Yearly issuance of CBs in MS
    3) Funding sources of European
    75
    c) Savings of funding costs for banks
    d) Overall savings in borrowing for
    the real economy
    banks and related costs
    Specific objective 2: diversify
    investor base
    e) Diversification of the investor
    base
    4) Investors by type
    Specific objective 3: tap potential
    for more cross border investments
    f) Percentage of cross-border
    investments
    5) Percentage of cross-border
    investments
    6) Investors by geography
    Specific objective 4: attract
    investors from outside the EU
    g) Percentage of covered bonds held
    outside the EU
    7) Percentage of covered bonds
    held outside the EU
    8) Inward-outward investments
    from/to third countries
    General Objective 2
    Coherence of EU prudential
    regulation
    Specific objective 1: align the
    structural characteristics of covered
    bonds across the EU
    No measurable benefit 9) CB enjoying LCR preferential
    treatment
    10) CB enjoying Solvency II
    preferential treatment
    11) Treatment of covered bonds in
    case of resolution
    12) Covered bonds in defaults
    Specific objective 2: strengthen
    the requirements for capital
    preferential treatment in CRR
    No measurable benefit 13) Issuance of 129 CRR compliant
    covered bonds
    Specific objective 3: define a
    framework for soft bullets/CPTs
    No measurable benefit 14) Share of soft bullet/CPT
    issuance
    15) Extensions of maturities for
    soft bullets/CPT
    Benchmark costs Monitoring indicators
    Direct administrative costs 16) Licensing fees
    17) Cover pool monitor costs
    18) Supervisory and regulatory fees
    19) Grandfathering
    Enforcement costs 20) Supervisory costs
    Indirect costs 21) Level of asset encumbrance
    Member States shall organise the production and gathering of the data necessary to measure
    the change in the indicators described in table 12 above, and shall supply that information to
    the Commission on a yearly basis.
    In particular, concerning the first indicator, the Commission will be in charge of monitoring
    the implementation of the directive according to EU law. Indicators 2, 4, 5, 6, 7 and 8 are to
    be collected through the help of market associations such as the ECBC. Indicators from 9 to
    15 and indicator 20 require the involvement of supervisors. Surveys among Member States'
    competent authorities will be used for this purpose. Indicators from 16 to 19 are to be
    provided both by supervisors and market associations. Surveys among Member States'
    competent authorities will be used for this purpose. However, indicator 17 will need the
    involvement of the industry, depending on the model of cover pool monitor adopted. Finally,
    concerning indicators 3 and 21, they are currently monitored by the EBA which reports
    periodically on them.
    76
    REFERENCES
    Banerjee A., V. Bystrov and P. D. Mizen (2013), “How Do Anticipated Changes to Short-
    Term Market Rates Influence Banks' Retail Interest Rates? Evidence from the Four Major
    Euro Area Economies”, in Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 45, 1375-1414.
    Birchler U.W. (2000), "Bankruptcy Priority for Bank Deposits: A Contract Theoretic
    Explanation", in Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 13, Issue 3, pp. 813–840.
    Borio C., and W. Fritz (1995), “The Response of Short-Term Bank Lending Rates to Policy
    Rates: a Cross Country Perspective.” BIS Working Paper No. 27.
    Chemla G. and C. Hennesy (2014), "Skin in the Game and Moral Hazard", in The journal of
    Finance, Vol. 69, Issue 4, pp. 1597–1641.
    Darracq-Paries M., Moccero N., Krylova E. and C.Marchini (2014), "The retail bank interest
    rate pass through: the case of the Euro Area during the financial and sovereign debt crisis",
    ECB Occasional Paper Series 155, September.
    De Bondt G. (2002), "Retail bank pass through: new evidence at the Euro Area level”, ECB
    Working Paper 136.
    De Graeve F., O. De Jonghe and R.V. Vennet (2007), “Competition, Transmission and Bank
    Pricing Policies: Evidence From Belgian Loan and Deposit Markets”, in Journal of Banking
    and Finance, Vol 31, pp. 259-278.
    Deutsche Bundesbank (2016), "Asset encumbrance, bank funding and financial fragility",
    https://www.bundesbank.de/Redaktion/EN/Downloads/Publications/Discussion_Paper_1/
    2016/2016_06_13_dkp_17.pdf?__blob=publicationFile
    EBA (2017a), "Report on asset encumbrance",
    https://www.eba.europa.eu/documents/10180/1720738/EBA+Report+on+Asset+Encumbr
    ance+-+July+2017.pdf
    EBA (2017b) "Report on Funding plans",
    https://www.eba.europa.eu/documents/10180/1720738/Report+on+Funding+Plans+-
    +July+2017.pdf )
    EBA (2016), "Report on covered bonds - Recommendations on Harmonisation of Covered
    Bond Frameworks in the EU", EBA-Op-2016-23, 20 December 2016:
    https://www.eba.europa.eu/documents/10180/1699643/EBA+Report+on+Covered+Bonds
    +%28EBA-Op-2016-23%29.pdf
    EBA (2014), "Report on EU covered bond frameworks and capital treatment", July 2014:
    https://www.eba.europa.eu/-/eba-supports-capital-treatment-of-covered-bonds-but-calls-
    for-additional-eligibility-criteria
    EBRD (2017), "Pan Baltic Covered Bond Structure - First Draft of the Proposal", 11
    September 2017.
    77
    ECBC (2013), "Position Paper on asset encumbrance", June 2013
    EMF and ECBC (2017), "Market Insights & Updates", February 2017.
    ESRB (2012), "Recommendation on funding of credit institutions" (ESRB/2012/2, Rec. E),
    December 2012:
    https://www.esrb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/recommendations/2012/ESRB_2012_2.en.pdf?8de39
    22e86b0f4863bc6e748f1f1a4c0
    European Commission (2017a). Communication on the Mid-term Review of the Capital
    Markets Union (CMU) Action Plan, COM (2017) 292 final, 08.06.2017.
    European Commission (2017b). "State of the Union 2017: Letter of Intent to President
    Antonio Tajani and to Prime Minister Juri Ratas":
    https://ec.europa.eu/commission/sites/beta-political/files/letter-of-intent-2017_en.pdf
    European Parliament (2017), Bernd Lucke (A8-0235/2017) "Towards a pan-European
    covered bonds framework", approved 4th
    July 2017.
    Gambacorta L. (2008), “How Do Banks Set Interest Rates?” in European Economic Review,
    Vol. 52, pp. 792-819.
    Hofmann B. and P.D. Mizen (2004), “Interest Rate Pass Through in the Monetary
    Transmission Mechanism: Evidence from Individual Financial Institutions Retail Rates”, in
    Economica, Vol 71, pp. 99-125.
    ICF (2017), "Covered Bonds in the European Union: harmonisation of legal frameworks and
    market behaviours", Study for the European Commission, May 2017.
    Illes A., Lombardi M. and P. Mizen (2015), "Why did bank lending rates diverge from policy
    rates after the financial crisis?", BIS Working Papers No 486, February.
    IMF, (2013), “Changes in bank funding patterns and financial stability risks”, Global
    Financial Stability Report, Ch 3, October 2013.
    Kwapil C. and J. Scharler (2010), “Interest Rate Pass-Through, Monetary Policy Rules and
    Macroeconomic Stability”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol 29, pp. 236-51.
    Van Rixtel A. and G. Gasperini (2013), “Financial crises and bank funding: Recent
    experience in the euro area”, BIS Working Paper 406.
    78
    ANNEX 1 - PROCEDURAL INFORMATION
    I. Lead dg, decide planning / cwp references
    This Impact Assessment Report was prepared by Directorate D "Regulation and prudential
    supervision of financial institutions" of the Directorate General "Directorate-General for
    Financial Stability, Financial Services and Capital Markets Union" (DG FISMA).
    The Decide Planning reference of the "Initiative on the integrated covered bond framework"
    is PLAN/2015/030.
    The initiative on the harmonisation of the covered bond market was included in the Mid-Term
    Review of the Capital Markets Union Action Plan from 08.06.2017.
    II. Organisation and timing
    Several services of the Commission with an interest in the assessment of the initiative have
    been associated in the development of this analysis.
    Three Inter-Service Steering Group (ISSG) meetings, consisting of representatives from
    various Directorates-General of the Commission, were held in 2017.
    The first meeting took place on 14 June 2017, attended by DG ECFIN, COMP, GROW,
    JUST, TRADE and the Secretariat General (SG).
    The second meeting was held on 18 July 2017. The representatives from DG ECFIN, JUST,
    GROW and the Secretariat General (SG) were present.
    The third meeting was held on 28 September 2017 and was attended by DG GROW and SG.
    This was the last meeting of the ISSG before the submission to the Regulatory Scrutiny Board
    on 6 October 2017.
    The meetings were chaired by SG.
    DG FISMA has updated the Impact Assessment Report by taking into account the comments
    made by SG, ECFIN, JUST and GROW. In particular, the following changes were made:
     The labelling system of the covered bonds was clarified, taking into account the
    discussions on the securitisation proposal, in particular the options of standalone
    labelling, third party verification or public confirmation.
     The absence of changes to the Solvency II framework was explained.
     The end of the ECB purchasing programme, and its consequences, were removed from
    the problem definition but left rather as an element of the context.
     CMU dimensions in the problem definition were broadened and clarified
     As regards the options further explanations on the eligibility of the assets under the
    option to develop a principle-based legislation have been included.
     The link of the initiative with the European Secured Notes has been clarified;
     Specific comments provided by DG ECFIN have been integrated in the document;
    79
     The new updated models of the Annexes provided in the revised toolbox
    https://myintracomm.ec.europa.eu/sg/better_regulation/Documents/tool_42.pdf have
    been used.
    III. Exceptions to the better regulation guidelines
    No exception from the Better Regulation Guidelines has been identified by DG FISMA.
    IV. Consultation of the regulatory scrutiny board (rsb)
    The Impact Assessment report was examined by the Regulatory Scrutiny Board on XX
    XXXX, 2017. The Board gave a XXXX opinion and …
    V. Evidence, sources and quality
    The impact assessment has been carried out with the comprehensive qualitative and
    quantitative evidence from various recognised sources, including the two reports by the
    European Banking Authority (EBA) and by taking account the findings of the commissioned
    study to an external consultant. The source of the analysis also included a targeted public
    consultation with stakeholders.
    The European Parliament's Own Initiative Report "Towards a pan-European covered bonds
    framework" has also been taken into account.
    In terms of milestones, in a response to the ESRB recommendation from 2012 on the
    preferential capital treatment of covered bonds, the EBA issued a ‘Report on EU covered
    bond frameworks and capital treatment' in 1 July 2014, identifying best practices with a view
    to ensuring robust and consistent frameworks for covered bonds across the EU. The report
    was made in close cooperation with the national competent authorities in the Subgroup on
    Securitisation & Covered Bonds. As a follow-up to the identification of best practices, the
    ESRB recommended to the EBA to monitor the functioning of the market for covered bonds
    by reference to these best practices for a period of 2 years.
    On 20 December 2016 the EBA delivered "Report on covered bonds - Recommendations on
    harmonisation of covered bond frameworks in the EU" to the ESRB and to the Council and
    the Commission containing an assessment of the functioning of the market for covered bonds
    under the best practice principles. This report was also made in the Subgroup on
    Securitisation and Covered Bonds.
    The report concluded that due to the confirmed existing diversity in national covered bond
    frameworks, significant market and regulatory developments with direct impact on covered
    bonds, and the overall importance of covered bonds for the funding of the EU economy,
    further harmonisation would be necessary in ensuring more consistency in terms of definition
    and regulatory treatment of covered bonds in the European Union. The report further
    concluded that harmonisation should build on the well-functioning markets already existing in
    some Member States.
    The EBA report announced its proposal for a three-step approach to the harmonisation of
    covered bond frameworks in the EU focussing on: (i) the development of a covered bond
    framework with the introduction of a new covered bond directive (Step 1); (ii) amendments to
    the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR) relating to the preferential risk-weight treatment
    (Step 2); and (iii) voluntary convergence (Step 3).
    80
    These three steps to harmonisation were proposed after the European Commission concluded
    the analysis of the responses received to the public consultation that was published in
    September 2015 and was aimed to assess the convenience of a possible future integrated
    European covered bond framework that could help improve funding conditions throughout the
    Union and facilitate cross-border investment and issuance in Member States.
    In August 2016 the European Commission commissioned a detailed study to an external
    consultant ICF on this proposal, assessing the potential costs and benefits of moving ahead
    with a legislative framework for the covered bonds. The Report was based on the following
    sources:
     A review and synthesis of relevant reports produced by the European Banking
    Authority (EBA), the European Central Bank (ECB), the European Covered Bonds
    Council (ECBC) and relevant academic and grey material.
     Quantitative and qualitative analysis of the responses received to the public
    consultation.
     Analysis of descriptive statistics compiled from a variety of sources including,
    published information from rating agencies, issuers and investment banks,
    unpublished analysis from rating agencies, issuers, issuer associations, and investment
    banks, the ECBC 2016 Factbook, the ECBC comparative database, the covered bond
    label website, the covered bond investor council website, and primary and secondary
    laws in Member State.
     Stakeholder interviews covering issuers, investors, supervisors/regulators, industry
    bodies and rating agencies.
     An online survey of issuers and national coordinators that received 61 responses.
    The report ‘Covered Bonds in the European Union: Harmonisation of legal frameworks and
    market behaviours’ was published in May 2017.
    The quality of the studies can be considered high as they represent the currently best available
    information on the covered bonds markets developments and include quantitative and
    qualitative input from all the identified stakeholders.
    81
    ANNEX 2 – SYNOPIS REPORT ON STAKEHOLDER CONSULTATIONS
    I. Overview of consultation activities
    1. ESRB Recommendation on the funding of credit institutions in December 2012;
    2. First EBA Report on EU Covered Bonds in July 2014;
    3. The Commission's open Public Consultation which ran between 30 September 2015
    and 06 January 2016, followed by a conference in February 2016 organized by DG
    FISMA;
    4. Public hearing held by the EBA in November 2016 before publishing the EBA report
    "Report on covered bonds - Recommendations on harmonisation of covered bond
    frameworks in the EU" in December 2016;
    5. Publication of the ICF study ‘Covered Bonds in the European Union: Harmonisation
    of legal frameworks and market behaviours’ based on stakeholder interviews and an
    online survey, in May 2017;
    6. Inception Impact Assessment on Covered Bonds published in June 2017;
    7. In July 2017 the European Parliament approves its own-initiative Report on covered
    bonds;
    8. Further stakeholder consultations, including meeting with Expert Group on Banking,
    Payments and Insurance in June and September 2017.
    II. Stakeholder consultations
    The Commission held an open Public Consultation to assess the convenience of a possible
    future integrated European covered bond framework. The Consultation Paper was meant to
    trigger a debate with stakeholders on the feasibility and potential merits of greater integration
    between covered bond laws.
    The consultation objective was to examine what weaknesses and vulnerabilities covered bond
    markets exhibited during the financial crisis and, against that backdrop, open a debate with all
    interested parties on the merits of targeted actions that could be taken to help improve funding
    conditions on the back of these instruments. This would be especially important where
    issuance faces legal or practical difficulties and where there are obstacles to cross-border
    investment flows within the Union and from third countries. The consultation is part of the
    Capital Markets Union project.
    The consultation was open to the public, but mainly received responses from the key
    stakeholder groups concerned with covered bonds:
     Covered bond issuers are credit institutions issuing covered bonds, either as their main
    business activity or as part of their general credit institution business. It should be
    noted that covered bonds issuers are often also covered bond investors as the issuers
    are credit institutions subject to requirements of liquidity coverage and capital.
     Covered bond investors are often institutional investors, dominated by banks and
    central banks, but asset managers, insurance companies and pension funds also play a
    significant role. Retail investors are represented indirectly by providing funds to
    pension funds and asset managers that then invest in covered bonds on their behalf.
    82
     As the special public supervision is considered to be one of the main structural
    features of covered bonds, the national competent authorities supervising the covered
    bond issuers are important stakeholders. Since there are large differences in the
    national covered bond frameworks, harmonisation could imply quite extensive
    regulatory work in some Member States, meaning that the national governments also
    have strong views in the harmonisation discussion.
     As covered bonds are all subject to external rating, the input from the rating agencies
    on their assessment of the different programmes and issuances is very relevant for
    further work on harmonisation. This especially regards transparency of the cover pool,
    liquidity risk mitigation and minimum overcollateralisation as these elements are
    considered important structural features of covered bonds and are regularly assessed
    by the rating agencies.
    1. European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) recommendation on funding of credit institutions-
    2012
    The ESRB recommendation on funding of credit institutions of 20 December 2012106
    recommended national supervisory authorities to incentivise the implementation of best
    practices regarding covered bonds, and the EBA to coordinate such initiatives and to identify
    best practices as well as to consider the functioning of the marketplace in accordance with the
    principles identified. The recommendation also called for the EBA to consider if appropriate
    to refer the matter to the European Commission for potential further action.
    2. European Banking Authority (EBA) "Report on EU covered bond frameworks and capital
    treatment" 1st July 2014
    Article 503(1) of Regulation (EU) No 575/2013 provides that the EBA shall be consulted by
    the Commission on whether the risk weights laid down in Article 129 of that Regulation are
    adequate for all the instruments that qualify for these treatments, whether the criteria in
    Article 129 of that Regulation are appropriate and whether loans secured by aircrafts (aircraft
    liens) and residential loans secured by a guarantee but not secured by a registered mortgage,
    should under certain conditions be considered an eligible asset. The Commission issued a call
    for advice accordingly and the EBA issued opinion on the preferential capital treatment of
    covered bonds recommending a further convergence of national legal/regulatory and
    supervisory covered bond frameworks, so as to further support the existence of a single
    preferential risk weight treatment to covered bonds in the EU.
    In a response to the ESRB recommendation and the Call for advice from the Commission, the
    EBA issued a ‘Report on EU covered bond frameworks and capital treatment' on 1st
    July
    2014107
    , identifying best practices. The report included the opinion of the European Banking
    106
    ESRB recommendation on funding of credit institutions (ESRB/2012/2, Recommendation E), December 2012
    (ESRB/2012/2):
    https://www.esrb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/recommendations/2012/ESRB_2012_2.en.pdf?8de3922e86b0f4863bc6e748
    f1f1a4c0
    107
    EBA report on EU covered bond frameworks and capital treatment, July 2014:
    https://www.eba.europa.eu/-/eba-supports-capital-treatment-of-covered-bonds-but-calls-for-additional-
    eligibility-criteria
    83
    Authority on the preferential capital treatment of covered bonds, also issued in response to the
    ESRB recommendation and the consultation of the EBA envisaged in Article 503 of the CRR.
    The report provided a first comprehensive overview, from the regulatory and supervisory
    perspective, of the EU (including Iceland and Norway) national covered bond frameworks. It
    identified a series of best practice recommendations to cover areas not reflected in common
    EU legislation with a view to ensuring robust and consistent frameworks for covered bonds
    across the EU.
    3. Public consultation on 'Covered Bonds'
    On 30 September 2015, the European Commission launched an open public consultation on
    Covered Bonds in the European Union. The consultation closed on 6 January 2016.
    The purpose of the consultation, which is part of the Capital Markets Union Action Plan, was
    to evaluate weaknesses and vulnerabilities in national covered bond markets as a result of the
    crisis and to assess the convenience of a possible future integrated European covered bond
    framework that could help improve funding conditions throughout the Union and facilitate
    cross-border investment and issuance in Member States currently facing practical or legal
    challenges in the development of their covered bond markets.
    All citizens and organisations were encouraged to contribute to the consultation.
    Contributions were particularly sought from participants in covered bond markets, the most
    relevant being investors, issuers and public authorities, but also rating agencies, organisations
    and other market participants. The list of the main stakeholders targeted in the consultation is
    provided at the beginning of Section II.
    The consultation paper was structured in three parts:
    1. Part I - Covered bond markets: economic analysis;
    2. Part II - Exploring the case for a more integrated framework;
    3. Part III - Elements for an integrated covered bond framework.
    The Commission received 76 responses. 19 responses came from the public sector and 57
    responses came from the private sector. The private sector responses divided into 27 from
    issuers, 11 from investors and the remaining 19 from other private sector stakeholders, such
    as cross-industry and consumer associations, rating agencies, surveyors, service providers and
    individuals.
    Geographic breakdown of responses:
    Cross-Europe 2
    Austria 3
    Belgium108
    13
    Czech Republic 3
    Denmark 3
    108
    Includes a number of Cross-Europe respondents based in Brussels
    84
    Finland 1
    France 5
    Germany 9
    Ireland 1
    Italy 3
    Luxembourg 2
    Norway 1
    Poland 4
    Slovakia 1
    Spain 4
    NA 21
    Overall, stakeholders agreed that covered bond markets showed increased yield divergence
    between Member States since 2007. Although stakeholders agreed that a robust legal
    framework would help to reduce volatility and ease market access in times of distress, they
    did not generally regard an absence of EU-level harmonisation as the most significant factor
    causing market fragmentation. Furthermore, even robust legal frameworks cannot fully isolate
    the covered bond programme from issuer's specific risks, making stakeholders also suggesting
    disclosure requirements to be substantially increased.
    While respondents were concerned that harmonisation based on a one-size-fits-all approach
    could risk impairing well-functioning markets and reducing flexibility and product offering, at
    the same time, they showed cautious support for EU targeted action, provided that
    harmonisation is principles based, build on existing frameworks and respect the unique
    characteristics of national frameworks.
    The public consultation introduced also a comprehensive EU law framework for covered
    bonds, a so-called 29th
    regime as a substitute for harmonisation. The rationale behind the 29th
    regime was to make a framework available for issuers to resort to as an alternative to national
    laws. This proposal did not find any support amongst stakeholders, all of them pointing to the
    increased market fragmentation, lower transparency and more uncertainty as a result of
    introducing a new system to complement the existing national systems. Stakeholders also
    expressed concerns about the possibility for issuances under the 29th
    regime to have a
    sufficient volume without introducing more favourable preferential treatment for issuances
    under the 29th
    regime than the existing regimes, thus disrupting the current market.
    In relation to market-led initiatives, respondents regard them as valuable but insufficient. For
    instance, while stakeholders consider the European "Covered Bond Label" as a positive step
    towards better integration of the covered bond markets, most acknowledge that there are
    certain limitations to self-regulation: voluntary arrangements cannot form the basis for a
    specific regulatory treatment so they need to be complemented by sound regulatory treatment,
    at national or European level. Public authorities in particular noted that a significant weakness
    of voluntary standards is that it would be up to issuers to comply with them in times of crises.
    The summary of the replies on the Open Public Consultation has been published here
    http://ec.europa.eu/finance/consultations/2015/covered-bonds/index_en.htm
    3.1. European Commission Conference on Covered Bonds
    85
    The European Commission conference on covered bonds was organized by DG FISMA on 1st
    February 2016. It included four sessions of panel debates with a short presentation from each
    of the 15 panellists. The panellists consisted of issuers, investors, supervisors, rating agencies,
    European Covered Bond Council (ECBC) - a market participant organisation, and capital
    market professionals.
    Every one of the panellists but the ECB was quite cautious about harmonisation, referring to
    the resilience of covered bonds during the financial crisis, and requesting the Commission not
    to mend something not broken. The discussion at the conference seemed more doubtful
    regarding harmonisation than the responses in the public consultation. This may be due to the
    fact that the national competent authorities and governments were not represented among the
    panellists which were mainly from the industry.
    Some panellists mentioned the 29th
    regime in their presentation, repeating the concerns
    expressed by most stakeholders in the public consultation.
    4. EBA "Report on covered bonds - Recommendations on harmonisation of covered bond
    frameworks in the EU" - 20 December 2016
    As a follow-up to the identification of best practices, the ESRB recommended to the EBA to
    monitor the functioning of the market for covered bonds by reference to these best practices
    for a period of 2 years. On 20 December 2016 the EBA delivered a "Report on covered bonds
    - Recommendations on harmonisation of covered bond frameworks in the EU"109
    to the ESRB
    and to the Council and the Commission containing an assessment of the functioning of the
    market for covered bonds under the best practice principles.
    In its Report on covered bonds the EBA proposes a three-step approach towards
    harmonisation of covered bonds, taking into account that EU covered bond frameworks differ
    in particular in regard to legal, regulatory, and supervisory issues, while acknowledging that
    the final framework should build on the strengths of existing national frameworks. This would
    still leave room for varying national implementation.
    Overall, the EBA proposes a three-step approach to harmonisation:
     Step 1 focusses on the structural aspects of a covered bond: Introduction of a
    harmonised definition of covered bonds, replacing Article 52(4) of the UCITS
    Directive with a dedicated directive to become the single point of reference of covered
    bonds for regulatory purposes;
     Step 2 addresses issues related to the preferential capital treatment of covered bonds.
    This would involve targeted amendments to Article 129 of the Capital Requirement
    Regulation;
     Step 3 includes voluntary measures at a national level.
    Drawing on the EBA recommendations, a potential EU legislative framework for covered
    bonds could comprise step 1 and 2.
    4.1. EBA Public Hearing on the report on covered bonds
    109
    EBA report on covered bonds, 20 December 2016:
    https://www.eba.europa.eu/documents/10180/1699643/EBA+Report+on+Covered+Bonds+%28EBA-Op-2016-
    23%29.pdf
    86
    The EBA held a public hearing in November 2016 before publishing the "Report on covered
    bonds - Recommendations on harmonisation of covered bond frameworks in the EU". The
    hearing was based on a presentation of the report which had not yet been published at the time
    of the hearing.
    The discussion at the hearing mainly concerned the more technical aspects of a future
    harmonisation, especially including the introduction of more costly requirements on liquidity
    and overcollateralisation, and the use of non-traditional amortisation structures.
    The report was not changed materially after the public hearing.
    5. Feedback on the Inception Impact Assessment on Covered Bonds
    The inception impact assessment on covered bonds was published on 9 June 2017 with a
    possibility to provide feedback until 7 July 2017.
    The Commission received four responses to the inception impact assessment. All of them
    supported the EU legislative initiative. The low number of respondents is most likely due to
    the very thorough public consultation ended in January 2016 followed by a well-attended
    conference 1st February 2016 and ongoing consultations with stakeholders since then, both at
    bilateral level and in the context of the Expert Group on Banking, Pension and Insurance
    meeting on 9 June 2017.
    The responses for the inception impact assessment came from Intesa Sanpaolo (Italy), Finance
    Denmark (The Danish organisation of issuers of covered bonds), the French Banking
    Federation and the Austrian Federal Economic Chamber (the legal representation of the
    Austrian Banking Industry).
    The responses related to specific issues of the national frameworks, the relation with specific
    requirements e.g. on liquidity, and repeated the general view of not jeopardising the well-
    functioning national systems, while still supporting harmonisation as such.
    6. ICF study ‘Covered Bonds in the European Union: Harmonisation of legal frameworks and
    market behaviours’
    European Commission requested in August 2016 a study from a third party contractor ICF on
    the potential impact on the covered bonds on the market110
    . The study assesses the current
    market performance and the costs and benefits of potential EU action. On the basis of a
    literature review; qualitative and quantitative analysis and stakeholder interviews, for a total
    of 106 organizations consulted in the period between November 2016 and February 2017, the
    study concluded there was a case for legislative action.
    The study was based on:
     A review and synthesis of relevant reports produced by the European Banking
    Authority (EBA), the European Central Bank (ECB), the European Covered Bonds
    Council (ECBC) and relevant academic and grey material.
    110
    ICF (2017), "Covered Bonds in the European Union: Harmonisation of legal frameworks and market
    behaviours". Study for the European Commission (May 2017).
    87
     Quantitative and qualitative analysis of the responses received to the public
    consultation.
     Analysis of descriptive statistics compiled from a variety of sources including,
    published information from rating agencies, issuers and investment banks,
    unpublished analysis from rating agencies, issuers, issuer associations, and investment
    banks, the ECBC 2016 Factbook, the ECBC comparative database, the covered bond
    label website, the covered bond investor council website, and primary and secondary
    laws in Member State.
     Stakeholder interviews covering issuers, investors, supervisors/regulators, industry
    bodies and rating agencies.
     An online survey of issuers and national coordinators that received 61 responses.
    The study determined that overall the potential benefits of a legislative framework
    outweighed any potential costs. The study took into account the EBA report findings. It
    recommended following the EBA report recommendations in step 1 and step 2.
    7. European Parliament own-initiative report on covered bonds approved on 4 July 2017
    European Parliament voted its own-initiative report on covered bonds on 4 July 2017111
    . The
    key points of the EU Parliament Report are that they favour legislation provided the approach
    is cautious. The EP stressed that the covered bond market has functioned well, while saying
    that diversity among covered bonds need to be maintained. It noted that an integrated
    framework needs to be principle-based, build on high-quality standards and aligning best
    practices
    The EU Parliament prefers that the new covered bond Directive should distinguish between
    ‘premium covered bonds’, which do adhere to the Article 129 of the CRR, and ‘ordinary
    covered bonds’, which would meet structural requirements set out in the directive.
    In addition, the report calls for a legal framework for ESNs, including the principles regarding
    dual recourse, asset segregation, bankruptcy remoteness, and transparency requirements.
    ESNs should also be exempted from bail-in.
    The EU parliament favours that covered bonds will only be backed by mortgages or public
    sector loans, while ESN could finance riskier assets, such as SME loans, consumer credit, or
    infrastructure loans without a government guarantee.
    EP stayed close to COMM and EBA in relation to defining covered bonds. It also noted that
    covered bonds issued by credit institutions from third countries should get a similar regulatory
    treatment if the legal, institutional and supervisory environment is equivalent to that in the
    EU. As such, the EU legislation could act as benchmark for the global covered bond market.
    8. Further stakeholder consultations
    111
    European Parliament Report: Bernd Lucke (A8-0235/2017), "Towards a pan-European covered bonds
    framework", approved 4th
    July 2017. http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=-
    //EP//TEXT+REPORT+A8-2017-0235+0+DOC+XML+V0//EN
    88
    The Commission has continued consulting stakeholders through meetings on key aspects of
    the proposal to help further substantiate the analysis of the available policy alternatives in line
    with Better Regulation guidelines.
    The stakeholder consultations are often initiated by the stakeholders wanting to address
    specific issues of their concern and also wanting to keep up with the harmonisation process.
    8.1. Expert Group on Banking, Payments and Insurance (EGBPI)
    The EGBPI has discussed the possible harmonisation of covered bonds on two meetings, the 9
    June 2017 and the 28 September 2017.
    At the first meeting the overall intention to have a three step approach in accordance with the
    EBA report from 2016 was presented and the decision announced on the CMU MTR was
    introduced. The majority of the Member States expressed support for the Commission
    approach and for keeping the ESNs as a separate instrument. In general, the discussion
    focused upon the harmonisation to be in line with the well-functioning national systems, and
    therefore most Member States specifically demanded for a harmonisation based on high level
    principles, some referring to the EBA report to be too detailed.
    At the second meeting the discussion was more detailed, but in general Member States were
    still in support of the principles based directive leaving room for national implementation and
    not jeopardising the systems already working well.
    III. Stakeholder input included in the harmonisations process
    The stakeholder input can be grouped into two categories:
    1. advice to change the existing framework to address concerns of a prudential nature
    2. request of not disrupting the existing well-functioning national systems.
    Stakeholder input belonging to the first group mainly came from the ESRB, the EBA, the
    ECB and to some extent from the national competent authorities in the Member States with
    well-developed covered bond markets and from the rating agencies.
    Stakeholder input belonging to the second group mainly came from Member States with well-
    developed covered bonds markets and from issuers and investors alike. They advocated the
    Commission being very careful not to unduly disrupt those markets working well, while
    acknowledging the need for harmonisation to ensure that the structural features of covered
    bonds are well integrated in all existing and upcoming markets.
    To include both types of stakeholder input, the Commission intends to define the structural
    features of the covered bonds in a directive, leaving room for national implementation. The
    Directive will be principles based to accommodate the wish of not changing the well-
    functioning market characteristics, but will include specific requirements addressing the areas
    considered necessary to ensure a prudentially solid framework.
    To specifically address the prudential concerns regarding capital preferential treatment the
    Commission intends to make targeted amendments to the CRR art 129 thus justifying a
    continuous preferential treatment.
    89
    90
    ANNEX 3 - WHO IS AFFECTED BY THE INITIATIVE AND HOW?
    I. Practical implications of the initiative
    Under the retained option (option 2: minimum harmonization based on national regimes)
    a harmonized legal framework for covered bonds would be established at EU level. This EU
    framework would aim at a minimum level of harmonization across the EU, building on the
    characteristics of existing national jurisdictions and seeking to avoid disrupting well-
    functioning markets. Under this option, the previous Article 52 of UCITS would be replaced
    by a new Directive defining the structural elements of covered bonds and Article 129 CRR
    would also be adjusted. This option will require Member States to transpose the new Directive
    into national legislation, and the issuers of and investors in covered bonds would have to
    adjust their businesses to changes in the resulting national frameworks. Grandfathering
    clauses would be foreseen for outstanding covered bonds.
    This option is supported by all stakeholders: institutional stakeholders, supervisors, Member
    States and industry stakeholders alike. In particular, the EBA, the ECB, the Parliament,
    national and European supervisors have advocated for option 2. This is the option that fits
    with the EBA advice and the EP Report. A majority of Member States is also favourable to
    this option. Among them all the largest markets. The ECBC representing almost all issuers in
    the market and investors is also in favour of this option.
    2. Summary of cost and benefits
    Benefits and costs of option 2 for each category of stakeholders have been summarized in
    table 1. Main benefits refer to issuers who would enjoy a lowering of funding costs and for
    citizens who would enjoy in their turn lower borrowing costs as well. Investors would benefit
    from a stronger regime that better protects them, however some details left to Member States’
    discretion could introduce weaknesses (for example in the relationship between extendible
    structures and liquidity buffer). Costs would increase for issuers and supervisors, while they
    would decrease for investors and society.
    Table 1– Impacts on different stakeholders of Option 2
    Issuers Investors Supervisors Citizens
    Benefits
    ↑↑ ↑ ↑
    ↑↑
    Costs
    ↑↑ ↓ ↑ ↓
    Tables 2 and 3 present the typical benefits and costs deriving from the specific actions to be
    undertaken in order to implement option 2. Benefits and costs are described for different
    categories of stakeholders, as applicable. In some cases, it is not possible to quantify impacts,
    in particular at a high level of detail. Furthermore, the baseline itself varies strongly across
    countries and these figures are not available in most cases. The exercise in the following
    tables will therefore mainly follow a descriptive approach and specific actions along with
    their benefits and costs will be described in detail.
    91
    Table 2– Overview of benefits: preferred option
    I. Overview of Benefits (total for all provisions) – Preferred Option
    Description Amount Comments
    Direct benefits
    Defining common standards
    for CB structural features
    1. Stimulate the development of CB markets,
    increasing issuance (between 50% and 75% of
    additional EUR 342 bn)
    2. Lowering costs of funding for issuers. At
    individual level: i. funding savings of 30-45 bps
    where CB issuance substitutes unsecured debt
    financing, ii. further funding savings of about 5 bps
    related to a more robust framework. At aggregate
    level funding costs savings of between 50% and
    75% of the benchmark long-term benefits of €2.2-
    2.7 billion per year.
    3. Diversify investor base (60% of investors other
    than banks)
    4. Facilitate cross-border investments
    5. Attract investors from third countries (16.5% of
    investments from third countries for additional
    EUR 115 bn in the long run from outside the EU)
    6. Strengthening investor protection
    7. Addressing prudential concerns
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) issuers
    b) investors
    c) citizens
    Defining principles for
    eligible cover assets and
    coverage requirements
    1. Strengthen the coverage requirements ensuring
    investors' rights
    2. Prudential benefits
    3. Reducing due diligence costs for investors
    4. Encourage issuance by smaller banks
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) investors
    b) issuers
    Define special public
    supervision
    1. Prudential benefits
    2. Strengthen investor protection
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) investors
    Define transparency
    requirements
    1. Reduced due diligence costs for investors
    compared to the baseline
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) investors
    Setting liquidity
    requirements
    1. Prudential benefits
    2. Strengthen investor protection
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) investors
    Define criteria for EMS 1. Address prudential concerns regarding market
    innovation
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) investors
    92
    2. Strengthen investor protection
    Setting overcollateralization
    requirements (between 2%
    and 5%)
    1. Strengthen investor protection in jurisdictions
    with lower levels
    2. Potential reduction of OC in jurisdictions with
    higher levels
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) investors
    b) issuers
    Setting rules for derivatives 1. Strengthen the coverage requirements ensuring
    investors' rights
    2. Hedging of currency/other risks
    3. Prudential benefits
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) investors
    b) issuers
    Other adjustments to art 129
    CRR
    1. Prudential benefits
    2. Strengthen investor protection
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) investors
    Indirect benefits
    Defining common standards
    for CB structural features
    1. Overall savings in borrowing costs for the real
    economy of between 50% and 75% of the
    benchmark long-term benefit of €1.5-1.9 billion per
    year.
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) citizens
    Setting overcollateralization
    and LTV limits only in CRR
    1. Reducing pro-cyclicality of LTV and
    overcollateralization requirements
    Stakeholders who benefit
    a) issuers
    b) citizens
    93
    Table 3– Overview of costs: preferred option
    II. Overview of costs – Preferred option(s)
    Citizens/Consumers Issuers/Investors Competent authorities
    One-off Recurrent One-off Recurrent One-off Recurrent
    Defining
    common
    standards for
    CB structural
    features,
    cover asset
    and
    transparency
    requirements.
    Direct
    costs
    NA NA Administrative
    and compliance
    costs for
    implementing
    changes (IT
    system, legal
    advice, credit
    rating, etc.). MS
    with lower costs
    would see an
    increase to
    benchmark
    levels of
    €590,000 to
    €1.8 mil.
    Administrative
    and
    compliance
    costs of new
    rules (audit
    and
    management,
    monitoring
    fees,
    supervisory,
    licensing
    costs). MS
    with lower
    costs would
    see an increase
    to benchmark
    levels of
    between
    €300,000 and
    €475,000/year.
    NA NA
    Indirect
    costs
    NA Stronger
    cover
    assets
    requiremen
    ts may
    reduce
    lending
    available
    for some
    segments
    NA Need of more
    collateral may
    reduce lending
    and increase
    asset
    encumbrance
    NA NA
    Define special
    public
    supervision
    Direct
    costs
    NA NA NA NA Adjustment
    to new
    supervision
    rules
    Higher
    enforcement
    costs
    (licensing,
    monitoring
    and auditing).
    "Light touch"
    jurisdictions
    would tend
    towards the
    benchmark
    of €25,350
    per issuer-
    year but the
    majority of
    them are not
    expected to
    hit the
    benchmark.
    94
    Indirect
    costs
    NA NA NA NA NA NA
    New liquidity
    requirements
    Direct
    costs
    NA NA Administrative
    costs for
    implementing
    the changes (i.e.
    IT system)
    1. Costs of
    carry of liquid
    assets in the
    cover pool
    (depending on
    level of
    interest rates)
    2. Lowering
    the availability
    of liquid assets
    Adjust
    supervision
    to new rules
    NA
    Indirect
    costs
    NA NA Higher issuance
    /conversions of
    EMS covered
    bonds
    (conversion
    costs of 0.05%).
    Transfer of
    liquidity risk
    on investors if
    EMS covered
    bond issuance
    NA NA
    New criteria
    for EMS
    Direct
    costs
    NA NA Administrative
    and compliance
    costs for
    implementing
    the changes (i.e.
    legal advice)
    NA Adjust
    supervision
    to new rules
    NA
    Indirect
    costs
    NA NA NA Shifting
    liquidity risk
    to investors
    NA NA
    Setting
    overcollaterali
    zation
    Direct
    costs
    NA NA Administrative
    and compliance
    costs for
    implementing
    the changes (i.e.
    IT systems,
    legal advice)
    Higher or
    lower costs of
    excess
    collateral,
    depending on
    jurisdiction
    Adjust
    supervision
    to new rules
    NA
    Indirect
    costs
    NA NA NA Increasing or
    reducing the
    level of asset
    encumbrance,
    depending on
    jurisdiction
    NA NA
    Setting rules
    for derivatives
    Direct
    costs
    NA NA Administrative
    and compliance
    costs for
    implementing
    the changes (i.e.
    IT systems and
    legal advice)
    Costs of
    monitoring
    derivatives in
    the cover pool
    Adjust
    supervision
    to new rules
    NA
    Indirect
    costs
    NA NA NA NA NA NA
    95
    Other
    adjustments to
    art 129 CRR
    Direct
    costs
    NA NA Administrative
    and compliance
    costs for
    implementing
    the changes (i.e.
    IT systems and
    legal advice)
    Costs of
    monitoring
    LTV limits
    and
    substitution
    cover assets
    Adjust
    supervision
    to new rules
    NA
    Indirect
    costs
    NA NA NA NA NA NA
    ANNEX 4 – ANALYTICAL METHODS USED TO CALCULATE BENEFITS
    This annex presents the methodology, the assumptions and the results of an illustrative
    estimation of the untapped potential of the EU covered bonds market in terms of additional
    issuance and funding cost benefits. The resulting figures should be considered as estimates of
    the maximum long-term potential annual savings in funding costs for a fully unified EU
    covered bond market.
    The estimates of funding benefits take the current level of bank lending as given. This
    assumption is rather conservative, as the supply of bank lending could increase as a result of
    better funding conditions for banks. It is also worth noting that the impacts are expressed in
    gross terms. In particular, the impacts on: i. issuance costs at the level of the individual issuer
    and ii. supervisory costs, are not taken into account in this calculation.
    I. Calculation of benefit benchmark b: additional issuance of covered bonds
    The starting point for estimating the additional issuance potential is the definition of a simple
    benchmark for the level of issued covered bonds, expressed relative to the size of Member
    States' banking sector. For this purpose, this analysis first calculates the ratio of total
    outstanding covered bonds issued in each Member State, divided by total outstanding loans
    issued by resident monetary and financial institutions excluding the Central bank.
    Next, the benchmark is defined as the median level of outstanding covered bonds among EU
    Member States considered as having an established covered bonds market.112
    A median-based
    benchmark is again a rather conservative choice, justified by the objective to minimize
    negative effects of asset encumbrance on the issuers' risk for unsecured creditors. Indeed, by
    definition, one-half of Member States with established markets currently operate with higher
    levels of CB issuance.
    It is further assumed that under a fully unified EU framework, countries below the benchmark
    level would gradually converge to this value in the long run (beyond a ten-year horizon),
    whilst countries currently above the benchmark are assumed to remain at their current level.
    Lastly, we assume that covered bond funding would be replacing unsecured debt funding.
    These two long-term funding options can be seen as natural substitutes for financing secured
    long-term lending, as suggested for example by Illes et al. (2015, p. 10).113
    The latter study
    also confirms that all EU Member States' banking sector seem to have sufficient levels of
    unsecured debt to be substituted by covered bonds.
    112
    Countries labeled for the purposes of this estimation as "Established markets" are Denmark, Sweden, Spain,
    Portugal, Finland, Austria, Germany, France, Italy, Netherlands, Belgium, and Luxembourg (ordered by the
    relative size of their outstanding covered bonds markets). Countries labelled as "Recent markets" are
    essentially the new Member States and countries whose covered bond frameworks have been introduced or
    significantly amended after the year 2000. This group of countries is composed of the Czech Republic,
    Slovakia, Ireland, Hungary, Greece, Cyprus, Poland, Bulgaria, Estonia, Croatia, Lithuania, Latvia, Malta,
    Romania, and Slovenia.
    113
    See A. Illes, M. Lombardi and P. Mizen (2015): 'Why did bank lending rates diverge from policy rates after
    the financial crisis?' BIS Working Papers No 486, February.
    97
    II. Calculation of benefit benchmark c: savings in terms of funding costs for banks
    issuing covered bonds
    Funding benefits related to additional CB issuance
    According to Fitch data, covered bonds get an uplift of between 3 and 6 notches in credit
    ratings in 80% of the programmes and on a quarter of them they get 4 notches uplift. This
    represents a significant improvement in credit ratings. The significantly better credit rating
    implies lower costs of funding for credit institutions114
    .
    The Commission services estimate115
    that for a representative sample of EU banks composing
    roughly 35% of the EU market for covered bonds, the cost of issuing covered bonds is on
    average 30bps to 45bps lower than for senior unsecured debt, other things being equal.116
    As
    can be seen in Figure 1, this benefit is larger for bonds with longer maturities. In addition, as
    expected, banks with lower credit ratings benefit more from issuing covered bonds than
    highly rated banks. For one bank in the sample the reduction in funding costs from issuing
    covered bonds is estimated to be up to 100bps.
    Figure 1. Difference in funding costs (z- spread) for covered bonds compared to senior
    unsecured debt
    Source: Commission Services estimates.
    114
    There is a negative relationship between credit ratings and interests paid to investors: the higher the credit
    rating, the lower the default risk and the lower the interest rate to be paid to investors.
    115
    Estimates are achieved by comparing z-spreads of outstanding covered bonds with the z-spreads of similar (in
    terms of currency, type of bonds, amount issued and maturity) senior unsecured bonds for the same bank. A
    total of 91 bonds were analysed from 26 different banks across 9 EU Member States. For France and
    Denmark, we compared covered bonds issued by specialised subsidiaries with similar bonds issued by
    parent companies.
    116
    According to the German association of Pfandbrief Banks (VdP), spread differentials between senior
    unsecured and covered bonds from a sample of selected large European covered bond issuers for securities
    with a 5 years maturity are even higher as they range between 60 and 70 bp. While it is true that covered
    bonds are more expensive to issue than unsecured debt, VdP estimates that the breakeven point of this
    spread that makes issuing covered bond not profitable anymore is around 20 basis points. However, this
    break-even figure has not been taken into consideration when calculating gross benefits of issuing covered
    bonds instead of unsecured debt for issuing banks.
    98
    These estimates were obtained by comparing the z-spreads117
    of outstanding covered bonds
    with similar senior unsecured bonds (same currency, type of bonds, amount issued and
    maturity) for the same bank. A total of 91 bonds were analysed from 26 different banks across
    9 EU Member States. For France and Denmark, covered bonds issued by specialised
    subsidiaries were compared with similar bonds issued by parent companies.
    The funding cost differentials of 30 bps to 45 bps are used to estimate the overall funding
    benefits of additional CB issuance on the assumption of unchanged yields for unsecured
    creditors.118
    The actual benefits could be closer to the low-end estimate of 30 bps, given
    possible effects of higher CB issuance on the perceived risk of less senior funding sources (as
    per a traditional Modigliani-Miller mechanism).
    The order of magnitude of the funding cost advantage of covered bonds relative to unsecured
    debt is confirmed by Illes et al. (2015). For 11 EU Member States, the study shows an average
    funding cost advantage for covered bonds of 82 bps before the global financial crisis, and 28
    bps during and after the crisis.
    Funding benefits related to reduced risk perceived by CB investors
    Funding costs benefits related to higher investor confidence under a more predictable and
    consistent framework across all EU Member States are more difficult to estimate. The
    external study funded by the Commission estimates these benefits based on expert judgment
    as multiple basis points, with 5 bps being a "relatively conservative estimate of the potential
    benefit".119
    This value is used for the evaluation of the benefit of a stronger EU framework for
    covered bonds.
    Anecdotal evidence may help substantiate this point. Proposed amendments to Slovakia's
    covered bond legislation aimed at addressing weaknesses in the current framework and at
    aligning it with European best practices are expected to come into force in January 2018.
    They would include credit strengthening characteristics (for example preventing an automatic
    acceleration of covered bonds when the issuer is under insolvency proceedings) which,
    according to Fitch, could induce the agency to improve the ratings of covered bonds issued
    under Slovakian law. At the same time, Fitch is concerned that other features of the proposal
    (for example the liquidity buffer) are weaker than in other countries and those aspects would
    need to be clarified before Slovakian covered bonds get the rating uplift. This example sheds
    some light on the potential of defining clear credit enhancing features for covered bonds at
    European level as this could help achieve credit enhancement and the related rating uplifts
    across the whole EU. In turn, better ratings would translate into lower yields for issuers.
    117
    Z-spreads are bond spreads that take into account, and correct for where necessary, for differences in the
    repayment of the principal of bonds. They are the most suitable spreads for comparison of different bonds.
    118
    Birchler (2000) shows how introducing different levels of debt priority can reduce the overall cost of funding
    of a bank. See U.W. Birchler (2000): "Bankruptcy Priority for Bank Deposits: A Contract Theoretic
    Explanation", Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 13, Issue 3, pp. 813–840.
    119
    ICF, 2017, p.55
    99
    III. Results
    The resulting estimates are presented in Table 1. Overall, under the above assumptions, the
    additional issuance potential for CB would be up to 342 EUR billion.
    This new issuance would entail an annual potential funding cost benefits between 2.2 and 2.7
    EUR billion in the long term.
    Using the estimated long-term pass-through rate by Illes et al. (2015) of about 70%, this could
    lead to potential annual savings for EU borrowers of 1.5 to 1.9 EUR billion in the long term.
    Table 1 – Illustrative estimation of additional issuance potential and funding benefits
    Source: Commission services.
    Note: The table shows a simplified estimate of the additional covered bond issuance potential, the annual
    funding cost benefits related to this additional issuance (the low and high end refer to a 30 bps resp. 45 bps
    saving compared to unsecured debt), and the annual funding cost benefits related to a lower risk perception by
    investors owing to a stronger CB framework.
    Low end High end
    (EUR bn) (% of loans) (EUR bn) (EUR bn) (EUR bn) (EUR bn)
    Denmark 391,1 61,1% 0,0 0,00 0,00 0,20
    Sweden 222,4 28,5% 0,0 0,00 0,00 0,11
    Spain 259,3 15,9% 0,0 0,00 0,00 0,13
    Portugal 33,5 13,8% 0,0 0,00 0,00 0,02
    Finland 33,8 10,9% 0,0 0,00 0,00 0,02
    Austria 48,0 9,0% 0,0 0,00 0,00 0,02
    Germany 373,8 8,0% 25,0 0,08 0,11 0,20
    Ireland 23,8 7,7% 2,6 0,01 0,01 0,01
    France 308,6 6,7% 81,8 0,25 0,37 0,20
    Italy 146,6 6,0% 60,2 0,18 0,27 0,10
    Netherlands 67,6 4,9% 50,9 0,15 0,23 0,06
    Belgium 19,0 3,4% 28,6 0,09 0,13 0,02
    Luxembourg 7,9 1,8% 29,5 0,09 0,13 0,02
    Czech Republic 13,1 8,8% 0,0 0,00 0,00 0,01
    Slovakia 4,2 8,2% 0,2 0,00 0,00 0,00
    Hungary 2,2 3,5% 3,1 0,01 0,01 0,00
    Greece 4,5 2,1% 13,3 0,04 0,06 0,01
    Cyprus 0,7 1,0% 4,9 0,01 0,02 0,00
    Poland 2,2 0,8% 21,2 0,06 0,10 0,01
    Bulgaria 0,0 0,0% 2,9 0,01 0,01 0,00
    Estonia 0,0 0,0% 1,9 0,01 0,01 0,00
    Croatia 0,0 0,0% 3,6 0,01 0,02 0,00
    Lithuania 0,0 0,0% 1,8 0,01 0,01 0,00
    Latvia 0,0 0,0% 1,6 0,00 0,01 0,00
    Malta 0,0 0,0% 1,4 0,00 0,01 0,00
    Romania 0,0 0,0% 5,3 0,02 0,02 0,00
    Slovenia 0,0 0,0% 2,3 0,01 0,01 0,00
    Total established 278,6 0,84 1,25 1,11
    Total new markets 63,4 0,19 0,29 0,05
    Total 342,0 1,03 1,54 1,15
    Established
    markets
    New markets
    CB outstanding CB outstanding
    Additional
    issuance
    potential
    Annual benefit of increased
    issuance
    Annual benefit
    of stronger
    regime
    100
    ANNEX 5 – FURTHER DATA AND EXPLANATIONS (COSTS)
    I. Costs of setting up and running a covered bond programme for an issuer
    There are significant upfront and ongoing costs involved in establishing and running a
    covered bond programme. These costs are a function of several factors such as: (i) the size of
    the covered bond programme of an issuer; (ii) the structure of the covered bond issuer. For
    example, issuance from a specialist credit institution involves significant additional costs
    when compared with issuance from universal credit institutions; and (iii) country specific
    factors such as legal and supervisory requirements.
    This section compiles data from various sources (online survey, OPC responses, Credit Rating
    Agencies and supervisors) collected by ICF to provide estimates of: (a) the initial costs of
    setting-up a covered bond programme; (b) the ongoing (annual) costs of running a covered
    bond programme; and (c) the costs of single issuance. It also compares the costs of covered
    bonds issuance as compared to other collateralised instruments.
    1. Upfront costs of establishing a covered bond programme
    The upfront costs of setting up a covered bond programme comprise:
     The cost of setting up IT systems to support the administration and management of the
    programme including risk management, monitoring and reporting of the cover assets
    etc. (see table below);
     Legal fees including the cost of a prospectus (see table below);
     Application and registration fees i.e. the cost of registering the programme with the
    regulator or supervisor (see table below);
     Investment bank fees - these are typically a function of maturity of the bond e.g. for a
    standard five year deal, investment banking fees would be of the order of 0.2% of the
    amount raised. Sometimes, an issuer does not pay any fees on the basis of an
    agreement that the issuer will use the investment bank for the first few bond deals
    and/or give that bank a disproportionate amount of the total fees payable on them120
    .
     Rating agencies’ fees - a minimum set-up and first issuance fee of €65,000 (limited
    approach) to €100,000 (full approach) for CEE issuers and €70,000- €150,000
    (Western Europe) is charged by Fitch Ratings. S&P charges a standard fee €85,000 for
    annual surveillance of a covered bond programme.
    Table 1. Covered bonds programme set-up costs: IT, legal and regulatory costs (based on survey
    responses)
    IT costs Legal fees
    Application &
    registration fees
    Belgium ~ €100,000 ~€250,000 ~€10,000
    Denmark €2 - 3.5 million €100,000 - €150,000 *
    Finland ~ €1 million €0.5 - 1 million ~€1,000
    France ~ €1 million €0.5 - 1 million ~€5,000 (AMF)
    120
    When a bond is launched typically three banks will run it for the issuer, each will get one third of the fees
    (€1bn bond x 20cent fees = €2mn / 3 banks = €666k each). Sometimes if one structured the programme the
    issuer might announce that the fee split is €1mn for the structurer, €0.5mn for the other two banks. The total
    fees paid don’t change but the structuring got recognised with a fee of €333k
    101
    IT costs Legal fees
    Application &
    registration fees
    €13,000 - €110,000
    Germany "substantial" "millions" €5,000 - €20,000
    Hungary : : ~€3,000
    Italy €150,000 - €1 million €200,000 - €300,000 €8,000 - €10,000
    Luxembourg €30,000 - €200,000 : :
    The Netherlands €100,000 - €300,000 €150,000 - €350,000 €10,000 - €25,000
    Poland : €250,000 - €300,000 :
    Portugal ~ €30,000 €20,000 - €350,000 €3,000 - €5,000
    Sweden €3 - 5 million €50,000 - €2 million €10,000 - €50,000
    The United Kingdom €100,000 - €2 million €550,000 - €1.2 million €27,500 - €50,000
    Source: ICF survey, n=40
    *Danish institutions do not pay explicitly for a license. The institutions under the supervision of Danish FSA pay
    for supervision in a broad sense according to specific formulas for allocating the total costs of running the
    Danish FSA to the different segments of institutions and within these different institutions in the specific segment.
    E.g. in a given year a mortgage credit institution under supervision applies for a license to issue covered bonds.
    This generates costs for the Danish FSA but these are not directly allocated to the institution in question; they
    are part of the total costs of DFSA allocated according to the system mentioned above. There is only a charge to
    an institution as such, and this is for the relative share of the cost of running the Danish FSA irrespective of the
    amount of bond issues that it makes.
    Overall, set-up costs range from hundreds of thousands to a few million euros across various
    EU jurisdictions.
    2. Ongoing costs of running a covered bond programme
    The annual costs of running a programme, as indicated by respondents to the ICF survey, are
    indicated in the table below.
    Table 2. Annual costs of running a covered bond programme (based on survey responses)
    IT costs Legal fees
    Cover pool
    monitor
    Audit fees
    Other
    supervision
    and regulatory
    costs
    Belgium ~ €10,000 ~ €25,000 ~ €80,000 ~ €50,000 (at start) :
    Denmark ~ €2 million €10,000 - €50,000 : ~ €70,000 ~€100,000
    Finland
    €150,000 -
    €200,000
    ~ €100,000 : ~ €30,000 ~ €20,000
    France
    €50,000 -
    €400,000
    €40,000 - €150,000
    €65,000 -
    €120,000*
    €100,000 -
    €850,000
    ~ €300,000
    Germany ~ €150,000 : €30,000 - 50,000** ~ €125,000***
    Hungary : : ~ €90,000 : :
    Ireland : ~ €300,000 ~ €200,000 ~ €100,000 €1 million
    Italy : €25,000 - €110,000 €20,000 - €60,000 €10,000 - €130,000
    €10,000 -
    €20,000
    Luxembour : : ~ €30,000 : :
    102
    IT costs Legal fees
    Cover pool
    monitor
    Audit fees
    Other
    supervision
    and regulatory
    costs
    g
    The
    Netherlands
    €10,000 -
    €100,000
    €40,000 - €250,000 €10,000 - €40,000 €10,000 - €60,000 €5,000 - €25,000
    Portugal ~ €5,000 €10,000 - €80,000 €25,000 - €30,000 €30,000 - €75,000
    €10,000 -
    €12,500
    Sweden
    €100,000 -
    €750,000
    €7,500 - €500,000 ~ €50,000 €10,000 - €50,000 €5,000 - €75,000
    The United
    Kingdom
    €60,000 -
    €240,000
    €60,000 - €180,000 €10,000 - €50,000 ~€120,000
    €120,000 - €2.2
    million
    Source: ICF survey, n=41
    * Appointing a Specific Controller is compulsory under French law. The Specific Controller is an audit firm
    different from the legal auditors of the CB Issuer or the parent group of the CB Issuer. The Specific Controller
    not only acts as a cover pool monitor but has wider functions. The annual cost of appointing a Specific
    Controller ranges from €50,000 to €300,000 depending of the size and complexity of the issuer (source: French
    controleur specifique).
    ** see annex X. The higher range applies to a large issuer with two alternate monitors
    ***includes cost of on-site cover pool audits which range from €10,000 for small savings banks to 6-digit
    amounts (at approx. €100,000) for major Pfandbrief banks, carried out by leading auditing firms. Additional
    supervision costs might include mandatory statements by chartered external auditors on appropriate
    organisation of the Pfandbrief business in the annual report + costs of internal control of observing the limits
    under the Pfandbrief Act + costs of coverpool insertion + lists of coverpool assets to be sent to BaFin. Some
    issuers carry out internal audits by their compliance departments, but this is not mandatory.
    Aside from above, issuers have to pay a fee to Credit Rating Agencies for annual surveillance
    of a covered bond programme. As indicated in the previous section, S&P charges a flat fee of
    €85,000 per programme. The fee charged by Fitch Ratings depends on the region and asset
    cover pool size – see table below.
    Table 3. Annual programme fees charged by Fitch Ratings (full approach)
    Assets Western Europe CEE
    Upto and including €2.5 billion €75,000 €40,000
    €2.5 – 5 billion €85,000 €50,000
    €5 – 10 billion €95,000 €60,000
    €10 – 15 billion €105,000 €80,000
    €15 – 25 billion €115,000 €80,000
    > €25 billion €130,000 €80,000
    Source: 2017 S&P fee schedule. For a limited approach, the fees are €50,000 for Western European issuers and
    €40,000 for CEE issuers regardless of asset cover pool size
    Survey respondents also indicated the following additional costs:
     Staffing costs for running the covered bond programme ;
     Cost of back office operations – these can be expected to be negligible once a covered
    bond programme has been set-up involving monthly running of reports or checking of
    accounting entries. Smaller issuers with less sophisticated IT systems might need to
    carry out manual intervention, in which case these would involve at most 0.5 FTE;
     Cost of professional bodies e.g. ECBC (€8,000 per year) and national industry body;
    103
     Cost of the covered bond label comprising121
    :
    - Initial Registration fee of €5,000 payable with the registration of a new cover pool
    - Annual Label fee of €3,800 in subsequent years where issuers will confirm/re-
    confirm their compliance to the Label Convention;
    - An additional volume issuance fee of €1 per million of new issuance (capped at
    €5,000 per year; not payable on the first year of a new Label).
     The fees and expenses of the Bond Trustee and Security Trustee (if any), ranging from
    €7,500 to €72,600
    3. Cost of single issuance
    The following costs are associated with each issuance:
     Rating fees: Fitch rating charges fees on all covered bond issuance as a percentage of
    the total issue size. The fees range from 0.25 bps (limited approach) to 1.0 bps (full
    approach) in Western European countries. A flat rate of 0.5 bps is charged in CEE
    countries. It should be noted that issuers often get 2-3 ratings for their issues;
     Legal fees per issue is typically either nothing or a very small amount, but for a small
    number of issuers (in particular those who do not issue from a standard programme),
    these could range from 100,000 to €300,000;
     The fees and expenses incurred or payable in connection with the listing of the covered
    bonds on stock markets. These can range from €4,000 in UK to €150,000 in Sweden.
     Fees relating to ISDA documentations (Swaps), which depends upon the number of
    counterparties an issuer has;
     In Hungary, audit fees are payable per issuance (~ €20,000 per issue).
    4. The costs of covered bonds issuance as compared to other collateralised instruments
    As indicated earlier, the upfront costs of establishing a covered bond programme amount to at
    least €0.5 million and are actually much higher in several EU jurisdictions. The ongoing costs
    are also high, ranging from €0.25 million to a few million euros.
    According to many respondents to the OPC, although the costs of setting up and running a
    covered bond programme are higher than other collateralised instruments in absolute terms,
    these can be spread across several issues, which eventually results in lower operational costs
    for covered bonds as compared to securitisations. Many respondents stated that the advantage
    of a covered bond programme is that once set up and registered, multiple transactions can be
    issued under the programme i.e., each new issuance benefits from the existing structure of the
    covered bond programme and bears only a fraction of the costs. In contrast, for each new
    ABS/RMBS issue, set up cost have to be incurred. Covered bonds are thus, regarded as a
    more efficient funding tool by market participants.
    The specific cost advantages of a covered bond programme over securitisation transactions
    are as follows:
     All covered bonds issued under a specific jurisdiction adhere to the same legislative
    requirements, whereas each securitisation transaction is a unique instrument with
    unique contractual agreements. Consequently for securitisation transaction, an issuer
    has to incur costs relating to due diligence of the portfolio; creation and maintenance
    121
    Covered bond label website: https://www.coveredbondlabel.com/procedures-label-fee [accessed 18.02.2017]
    104
    of ad hoc structures such as SPVs; developing legal documentation; and advisory and
    rating costs (which are usually much higher for securitisation transactions as compared
    to covered bonds122
    ).
     The ability to provide a single investor reporting for an entire covered bond
    programme is less costly as compared individual securitisations.
     A single swap covering a covered bond issue is also less costly than multiple swaps for
    heterogeneous securitisation transactions.
     Securitisation transactions often involve the constitution of the legal entity (SPV) and
    the need for two different credit ratings, which implies additional costs.
    Finally, from an investor’s perspective, due diligence costs are lower for covered bonds as it
    is a more standardised product compared to securitisations.
    II. Cost of supervision
    Within the framework of this study, detailed data was also collected from supervisors in three
    jurisdictions representing different supervisory regimes. The findings are reported below.
    1. Denmark
    The key tasks from the supervisory perspective in the Danish context entail the following123
    :
     Issuance of license – one off covered bond specific licensing;
     Period review and analysis of the data/ documentation provided by the issuer;124
     Periodic quality check of cover assets including checks on eligibility of assets and real
    estate valuations practices and outcomes (NB: This includes regular on-site visits)
     Periodic Monitoring of the exposure of the covered bond programme to market risk
    and liquidity risk;
     Periodic checks of minimum mandatory over collateralisation requirements;
     Evaluation of operational risks of the issuer.
    Supervision of mortgage credit institutions is carried out by the Danish FSA. The basic rule is
    that the institutions under supervision pay for the costs associated with their supervision. The
    cost of running the Danish FSA is therefore, allocated to the different units under supervision
    based on different measures. In practice there is an allocation to each group of institutions in
    question, e.g. mortgage bank, universal bank, insurance company, investment fund, etc.
    Within these groups the allocated costs are further allocated based on different measures.
    Mortgage banks as a group pay 13.2% of the annual costs of the Danish FSA. Additional
    fixed fees apply to certain units under supervision, although these are largely insignificant in
    comparison. Within the group of mortgage banks this amount is divided between the
    mortgage banks according to their total assets.
    As a rough estimate, circa 17 FTEs across different departments of the Danish FSA are
    involved in supervising covered bond programmes (of which roughly 3.5 FTEs are involved
    122
    This is because securitisation transactions are more complex, involving the creation of ad hoc structures,
    leveraged nature of tranche-structures (several tranches which are collateralised by the same asset pool are
    rated separately)
    123
    ECBC, 2017. Comparison of frameworks. Available at: http://www.ecbc.eu/framework/freeCompare and
    EBA, 2014. EBA Report on EU Covered Bond Framework and Capital. Available at:
    https://www.eba.europa.eu/documents/10180/534414/EBA+Report+on+EU+Covered+Bond+Frameworks+
    and+Capital+Treatment.pdf
    124
    For instance, reports of mortgage banks to the Danish FSA are provided on the quarterly basis and cover
    credit risk exposure, market risk exposure and solvency
    105
    in on-site inspections of covered bond issuers). The average salary cost per FTE is 650,000
    DKK (~ €87,400). In addition, the average overhead per FTE is 390,000 DKK (~ €52,450).
    The annual costs incurred by the Danish FSA can be estimated at ~ €2.4 million. Considering
    that there are 9-10 issuers in Denmark, the average cost of supervision works out as €237,745
    - €264,161. The average cost per covered bond programme can be estimated as €103,367
    (based on ECBC data on the number of programmes = 23 in 2014 and 2015).
    2. France
    The supervisory regime for covered bonds comprises several entities. Some with no specific
    role in relation to covered bonds and some with a specific role.
    The two bodies with no specific role in relation to the covered bond framework are:
     AMF (Market supervisor): since as issuers of debt securities, covered bond issuers
    have to prepare a prospectus and submit it for AMF approval.
     Legal/ statutory auditors: as credit institutions, covered bond issuers need to have two
    legal auditors of their accounts.
    The two bodies with specific roles in relation to the covered bond framework are the ACPR
    and the Specific controller, which will be the focus of this section.
    Regulatory Supervisor (ACPR)
    The main functions of the ACPR are:
     Approval of the establishment of the CB Issuer/program
     On-going supervision (based on quarterly and annual regulatory reports received from
    the Specific Controller, interviews and due diligences of the Specific Controller)
     Investigation rights: on-site inspections of covered bond issuers by the ACPR itself are
    not frequent (for illustrative purposes, it can be assumed that over a ten-year period, a
    covered bond issuer would typically have one chance in three to be inspected). In case
    they are performed though, these are in-depth inspections lasting several weeks or
    months.
    The regular inspections are carried out by the Specific Controller who then reports to the
    ACPR.
    At the ACPR, the special public supervision of the CB issuers is conducted by the banking
    supervision teams, along with their supervision under CRD4-CRR (covered bonds issuers
    being credit institutions in French law). Estimates of costs pertaining specifically to CB-
    specific public supervision are not readily available (as there are no CB dedicated teams /
    individuals and costs do not appear separately in ACPR analytical accounting).
    As credit institutions under French law, covered bond issuers are subject to the same fees as
    any other credit institution (or “contribution pour frais de contrôle”) according to article
    L.612-20 of the Code Monétaire et Financier. In this case, being a CB issuer does not imply
    specific treatment and the amount is not related to the work done by the supervisor for
    monitoring the cover pool of covered bond issuers.
    Specific Controller (art. L.513-23 of CMF)
    106
    The existence and appointment of the Specific Controller is enshrined in the French
    legal/regulatory covered bond framework: he/she is not appointed following a contractual
    agreement with the issuer as is frequent for cover pool monitors in other jurisdictions.
    Although part of the public supervisory regime, the Special Controller is a staff member of a
    private audit firm (different from the firm auditing the accounts of the CB Issuer or the parent
    group of the CB Issuer to guarantee independence and absence of conflict of interest). The
    Specific Controller, a professional registered to the CNCC (French Audit Association), is
    chosen by the issuer after approval from the supervisor (ACPR).
    The fees of the Specific Controller are 100% charged to the Issuer. These costs range from
    €50,000 to €300,000 per year depending of the size and complexity of each issuer.
    The responsibilities of the Specific Controller (wider than the tasks of cover pool monitors in
    other countries as he/she undertakes part of the tasks typically undertaken by the supervisor)
    are as follows:
     Controls the eligibility of cover pool assets based on tests conducted on a
    representative sample of cover pool assets (generally on annual basis)
     Controls issuer’s compliance with the regulatory calculation requirements: OC,
    liquidity buffer, maturity gap, coverage plan on a quarterly basis and issues a quarterly
    review certification
     Controls the compliance of valuation methods applied to cover assets (properties) for
    cover pools based on home loans (annual certification, which is disclosed with the
    financial statements of the CB Issuer)
     Must alert the supervisor and the management if the matching in terms of maturity,
    currency or interest rate appears excessively unsafe and jeopardizes the bondholders
     Delivers pre-issuance controls ensuring that new forecasted issuances would not entail
    a breach of any regulatory requirements (on a quarterly basis; quarterly review
    certification + specific review certification for each issuance > €500 million).
    Germany
    Licensing
    Fees are levied for certain activities in relation to Pfandbrief business (cf. specifically
    section 2 of the schedule of fees, appendix to FinDAGKostV, http://www.gesetze-im-
    internet.de/findagkostv/anlage.html, German only), most relevant are:
     the fee for extending the license to conduct Pfandbrief business (for establishment of
    credit institution including Pfandbrief business the fee for the entire licensing process
    ranges between €5,000 and 20,000; for the more common case of extending an already
    existing license to also include Pfandbrief business, the fee is 25% to 100% of the
    “establishment” fee), and
     the fee for appointing a cover pool monitor (first-time appointment €305; extension of
    appointment €140).
    107
    The rest of the existing Pfandbrief-related types of fees, typically in relation to BaFin’s
    waiving of certain requirements as provided for by the Pfandbrief Act, have no practical
    relevance. Beyond this, no specific attribution of costs to Pfandbrief banks for Pfandbrief-
    related supervisory activities applies; these costs thus are borne by way of all supervised
    entities being apportioned a share in BaFin’s costs not yet borne otherwise
    (“Umlagefinanzierung”).
    Cover pool monitor (annual)
    In Germany, the cover pool monitor (CPM) is appointed by BaFin. S/he is not BaFin staff, but
    an independent individual. The CPM is remunerated according to fees set by BaFin, as well as
    reimbursement of necessary expenses, in both instances to be paid by the Pfandbrief bank.
    The Pfandbrief bank is prohibited to award any additional benefits to the CPM. The scheme
    for setting CPM’s compensation on a monthly basis is composed of a fixed amount (€700), a
    variable add-on in response to Pfandbriefe in circulation (the variable add-on amount is
    expressed as a %-point of the fixed amount; ranges from 0% - circulation below €1,000mn to
    175% for circulation above €30,000mn), and a premium (+25%-points in case of cover pools
    composed mainly of complex CRE financings or complex public sector financings or a very
    high number of retail RRE financings; individually, the premium rate may be set at +50%-
    points if thoroughly justified) or rebate (-25%-points in case of non-complex ship financings
    or other large lot-size financings, or to compensate for high degree of work participation of
    deputy CPM) for certain individual aspects applicable to the variable add-on. The maximum
    compensation without individual adjustments thus amounts to a fixed amount of €700 + 175%
    of fixed amount €1,225 = €1,925 Euro for circulation above €30bn. The monthly
    remuneration of a CPM thus, varies between € 700 and 1,925.
    On-site cover pool audits (conducted at two two-year intervals)
    Department BA 57 at BaFin is responsible for conducting cover pool audits at Pfandbrief
    banks at two year intervals, either using its own staff (appraisers), or CPAs, experienced in
    the area of Pfandbrief cover pool audits (selected through a tendering process). Cost incurred
    due to a cover pool audit (ordered by reference to sec. 44 par. 1 of the Banking Act), are fully
    recoverable from the audited credit institution, cf. sec. 15 par. 1 no. 1 FinDAG
    (http://www.gesetze-im-internet.de/findag/__15.html, German only).
    In case of cover pool audits performed by BaFin’s own staff, the costs of cover pool audits,
    including travel expenses and offsite quality assurance activities are debited to the audited
    Pfandbrief bank.
    In the latter case, BaFin launches and evaluates the tender, appoints a CPA to conduct the
    audit, evaluates the audit report, initiates transmission of the audit report to the audited
    Pfandbrief bank, and carries out any follow-up. Although BaFin commissions the audit
    contract, the auditing CPA typically is paid directly by the audited Pfandbrief bank.
    Table 4. Cost of cover pool audits conducted at two year intervals, 2015
    Number of cover
    pool audits
    Total costs Average costs
    CPA*
    17 €718,000 €42,000
    own staff 8 €224,000 €28,000
    108
    Source: BaFin. Due to reorganisation of department BA 57 in 2014, and data for financial year 2016 not having
    been finalised, the following data have been compiled for 2015. * refers to tenders completed in 2015
    BA 57 total (100% FTE) budget for 2015 (with approximately 78% FTE dedicated for cover
    pool audit and supplementary functions) was as follows:
     Direct costs: €1.55 million (of which direct staffing costs: €1.51 million)
     Overhead costs: €1.18 million
    The costs not recovered from Pfandbrief banks are funded as part of BaFin’s general budget
    (i.e. via cost allocation to supervised entities, where being a Pfandbrief bank would not imply
    specific treatment).
    109
    ANNEX 6 – IMPLEMENTING THE RETAINED OPTION
    4. The tables below describe the detailed provisions under the retained option specifying
    for each of them whether and how they deviate from the EBA 2016 Report and how they
    differ from the current situation in Member States where a legal covered bond framework is in
    place.
    5. Retained
    Option (minimum
    harmonisation via
    directive)
    6. EBA 7. Explanatio
    n for deviating from
    EBA
    8. Situation
    in Member States
    (MS)
    9. Comments
    on impacts on MS
    10. Dual recourse 11. No
    difference
    12. NA 13. All MS
    compliant
    14. No
    significant changes
    for the majority of
    MS
    15. Bankruptcy
    remoteness of covered
    bonds
    16. Simila
    r approach on
    the structural
    feature, but
    limited
    deviations for
    operational
    plans envisaged
    by the EBA.
    17. No
    requirements for
    operational plans in
    order to be
    principles based and
    to avoid any
    duplication with
    BRRD resolution
    plans.
    18. Very high
    level of
    compliance
    regarding the
    structural features
    19. No
    significant changes
    for the majority of
    MS
    20. Eligible assets
    (define principles to
    limit assets to high
    quality only, not listing
    assets in the Directive,
    only in the CRR)
    21. Same
    approach
    22. NA 23. Main
    assets: mortgages;
    public loans, ships,
    aircraft. Some MS
    have a smaller
    amount of less
    traditional assets.
    24.
    25. For some
    MS there could be
    limitations in
    comparison with
    current situation.
    26. Assets located
    outside the EU
    (allowed under control
    by CAs)
    27. For the
    EBA is step 3
    (voluntary
    convergence)
    based on
    COMM
    equivalence.
    28. We
    regulate in the
    Directive for
    prudential reasons
    and we leave
    decisions to MS for
    efficiency reasons.
    29. High level
    of compliance
    30. Minor
    changes foreseen for
    some MS
    31. Intragroup CB
    and joint funding
    (allowed)
    32. Not
    mentioned
    33. More CMU
    relevant than
    prudential.
    34. NA 35. Important to
    have for business
    models in some MS
    36. Segregation of
    cover assets
    37. Same
    approach
    38. NA 39. Nearly all
    MS compliant
    40. Concentrate
    d impact in a few MS
    41. Derivatives in
    the cover pool (allowed
    for hedging purposes
    only and part of
    segregation and
    42. EBA
    more detailed
    on coverage
    requirement
    calculations
    43. Less details
    as we want to be
    principle based
    44. High level
    of compliance
    45. No
    significant changes
    for the majority of
    MS
    110
    coverage requirements) and on
    eligibility
    criteria for
    counterparties
    46. Cover pool
    monitor (optional and
    details left to MS)
    47. The
    EBA requires
    this as
    mandatory and
    requires the
    details on
    appointment,
    eligibility
    criteria and
    main duties and
    powers to be
    defined in the
    Directive. EBA
    acknowledges
    tasks of
    monitor to be
    performed by
    special public
    supervisor.
    48. Emphasis
    on the special public
    supervisor as the
    ultimate responsible
    for investor
    protection and to
    avoid confusion on
    supervisory
    responsibility. Need
    to be principles
    based and to avoid
    listing details in the
    directive on
    appointment,
    eligibility and main
    duties and powers of
    the monitor.
    49. The
    majority of MS has
    a mandatory cover
    pool monitor. The
    rest have the tasks
    performed by the
    special public
    supervisor.
    50. Costs only
    for countries where
    the monitor is not
    currently envisaged
    and who choose to
    make it mandatory.
    51. Transparency
    (strengthened and
    moved from CRR to
    Directive)
    52. Same
    approach in
    terms of
    frequency,
    details and
    directive level
    53. NA 54. Impact
    mainly relating to
    frequency. HTT
    already ensuring
    common high level
    of transparency.
    55. Limited.
    56. Coverage
    requirement (nominal
    method as floor)
    57. Same
    approach
    58. NA 59. High level
    of compliance
    60. Limited.
    61. Liquidity
    buffer (to cover 180
    days with no
    overlapping with LCR)
    62. Same
    approach for
    the size (180
    days), position
    in relation to
    coverage
    requirements
    and
    segregation,
    exceptions.
    Differences
    concerning the
    composition of
    the buffer,
    valuation,
    interaction with
    LCR. The EBA
    envisages a
    further
    assessment.
    63. We do not
    want to touch on the
    LCR, we want to
    avoid any
    duplication with it
    and ensure
    compliance with
    LCR provisions.
    64. All MS
    currently have
    some liquidity risk
    mitigation
    requirements in
    place.
    65. As LCR is
    not affected, the
    impact is limited.
    66. Extendable
    maturity structures
    (triggers effected not at
    67. Same
    approach
    68. NA 69. Only 2
    MS having a
    framework in place
    70.
    111
    the discretion of the
    issuer)
    concerning
    extendable
    maturity structures.
    71. Special public
    supervision (with
    national authorities not
    linked with credit
    institution supervision)
    72. Same
    approach
    concerning the
    content of the
    supervision. No
    mention of the
    level whether
    EU or national.
    73. NA 74. For some
    MS supervision
    will have to be
    strengthened.
    75. This would
    imply increased costs
    in MS where
    currently supervision
    is too light.
    76. Permission to
    issue CB (by special
    supervisors)
    77. Same
    approach
    78. NA 79. For a
    number of MS the
    permission
    framework will
    have to change.
    80. This would
    imply increased
    costs.
    81. EU label
    (coexisting with
    national labels, not
    specifically granted)
    82. Not
    envisaged
    83. NA 84. Coexistin
    g
    85. No specific
    costs
    86. Equivalence
    regime (postponed to
    review report in two
    years time)
    87. Not
    assessed
    88. NA 89. Not
    existent
    90. No specific
    costs
    91. Grandfatherin
    g (yes)
    92. Not
    assessed
    93. NA 94. 95.
    96.
    97.
    98. Changes
    in the CRR
    99. EBA 100. Explanation
    for deviating from
    EBA
    101. Situation
    in MS
    102. Comments
    on impacts for MS
    103. LTV
    limits (soft)
    104. Same
    approach
    105. NA 106. High level
    of compliance
    107. No
    significant changes
    for the majority of
    MS
    108. OC (risk
    based 2%-5%)
    109. Same
    approach for
    application of OC
    to CRR compliant
    only CB and
    method of
    calculation
    (nominal). We
    deviate for the
    level: 5% for the
    EBA, while we
    chose a risk based
    approach ranging
    between 2% and
    111. A risk based
    approach makes
    sense to link the level
    of
    overcollateralisation
    to the level of risk in
    the cover pool.
    Moreover, for some
    MS, 5% would be too
    high (DK and DE in
    particular), while for
    others 2% would be
    too low.
    112. Almost all
    MS have some OC
    requirements today
    set at different
    levels.
    113. The risk
    based approach
    entails lower costs
    than the 5%
    threshold envisaged
    by the EBA for all.
    112
    5% The EBA left
    the evaluation of
    the level open to
    further analysis.
    110.
    113
    ANNEX 7 - GLOSSARY
    Acceleration of a covered bond Covered bonds are declared to be
    immediately due and payable, thus moving
    the payments to the bond holder to an earlier
    time than the original maturity date, typically
    due to default of the issuer and subject to
    strict demands.
    Asset encumbrance The percentage of assets on a bank’s balance
    sheet pledged or otherwise used as security,
    including, inter alia to covered bond holders.
    Bankruptcy remoteness of the covered bond Meaning the covered bond may not
    automatically accelerate upon the issuer’s
    insolvency or resolution.
    BRRD Directive 2014/59/EU establishing a
    framework for the recovery and resolution of
    credit institutions and investment firms (Bank
    Recovery and Resolution Directive).
    Bullet structures Covered bonds with soft-bullet structures
    provide for the possibility to extend the
    scheduled maturity for a certain period of
    time. Typically, this might be 12 months, but
    can also result in the structure becoming
    "pass-through" under specific conditions
    (conditional pass-through/CPT), which means
    that the cash flows from the assets in the
    cover pool are passed directly to the covered
    bond holders. The extension triggers may
    vary and can be defined by law, at the
    discretion of the issuer or a result of non-
    payment on the scheduled maturity date.
    CMU CMU is the Capital Markets Union, a plan of
    the European Commission to mobilise capital
    and establish a genuine single capital market
    in the EU.
    Competent authority The authority vested by the national covered
    bond regime with the function of exercising
    special public supervision for the benefit of
    the covered bond investors. The competent
    authority is not necessarily the same authority
    as the one responsible for the general
    prudential supervision of credit institutions.
    Cover assets The assets eligible for serving as security in a
    114
    cover pool
    Covered bond programme Refers to the perimeter of claims and
    obligations as well as activities related to a
    specific covered bond product of the issuer,
    and to which protective measures of the
    respective covered bond regime would apply
    in the issuer’s insolvency. Different issuances
    (different International Securities
    Identification Numbers (ISINs)) of the same
    covered bond programme do not necessarily
    constitute separate covered bond
    programmes. The term ‘covered bond
    programme’ can also be referring to covered
    bond activities executed by specialised
    covered bond issuers in some jurisdictions,
    where a licencing procedure refers to covered
    bond activities rather than to covered bond
    programmes.
    Cover pool The pool of assets that, at any point in time,
    constitute the security for the covered bonds.
    They must be segregated from other assets
    owned by the issuer to ensure certainty of
    bondholder claim.
    Cover pool monitor An internal or external entity other than the
    ordinary auditor of the covered bonds issuer,
    monitoring specific tasks of the issuance of
    covered bonds in going concern, e.g.
    verifying coverage tests or signing off
    inclusion and removal of cover assets in/from
    the cover pool
    Coverage requirement Article 52(4) of the UCITS Directive
    establishes the coverage principle of covered
    bonds requiring that, during the whole period
    of the bonds’ validity, the assets underlying
    the covered bonds must be capable of
    covering claims attached to the bonds. The
    EBA report 2016 recommends coverage
    requirements to be part of a common
    framework.
    CBPP The Covered Bond Purchase Programme, a
    programme originally instituted in 2009 by
    the European Central Bank to support a
    specific financial market segment by
    purchasing covered bonds. CBPP3 is the third
    and latest purchase programme, started in
    October 2014.
    115
    CEE Central and Eastern European countries
    CPT/conditional pass through See "Bullet structures"
    CRR Regulation No 575/2013 on prudential
    requirements for credit institutions and
    investment firms (capital requirements
    regulation)
    Dual recourse The dual recourse secures the covered bond
    investor a claim on both the cover pool and
    the issuer.
    EBA report 2014 EBA report on EU covered bond frameworks
    and capital treatment –
    Response to the Commission’s call for advice
    of December 2013 related to Article 503 of
    the Regulation (EU) No 575/2013 and to the
    ESRB Recommendation E on the funding of
    credit institutions of December 2012
    (ESRB/12/2), published July 2014
    EBA report 2016 EBA report on covered bonds –
    Recommendations on harmonisation of
    covered bond frameworks in the EU,
    published December 2016
    EBRD European Bank for Reconstruction and
    Development
    ECB European Central Bank
    ECBC European Covered Bond Council, created by
    the European Mortgage Federation (EMF) in
    2004 to represent and promote the interests of
    covered bond market participants at the
    international level.
    EMIR Regulation (EU) No 648/2012 on OTC
    derivatives, central counterparties and trade
    repositories (European Markets Infrastructure
    Regulations).
    EMS Extendible Maturity Structures (see bullet
    structures)
    ESN European Secured Notes is as a dual-recourse
    financial instrument on an issuer's balance
    sheet applying the basic structural
    characteristics of covered bonds to two non-
    traditional cover pool assets - SME bank
    loans and infrastructure bank loans. ESNs are
    116
    originally suggested by the ECBC, supported
    in the EP report and currently being
    examined by the Commission to assess the
    case for legislative action.
    EP report Report from the Committee on Economic and
    Monetary Affairs: Towards a pan-European
    covered bonds framework, adopted in June
    2017
    HTT/Harmonised Transparency Template Template introduced by ECBC. Standardised,
    Excel-based form that issuers who have been
    granted the Covered Bond Label by ECBC
    use to disclose information on their covered
    bond programs.
    LTV Loan-to-value. The ratio between the loan
    and the value of the asset serving as
    collateral.
    LCR The liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) refers to
    the demands for highly liquid assets to be
    held by financial institutions to meet short-
    term obligations.
    LCR Delegated Act Commission Delegated Regulation (EU)
    2015/61 to supplement Regulation (EU) No
    575/2013 with regard to liquidity coverage
    requirement for Credit Institutions
    Overcollateralisation/OC The level of collateral exceeding the coverage
    requirement. Can be statutory or contractual
    (used to support the credit rating treatment of
    the bonds).
    Segregation of cover assets The legally binding and enforceable
    arrangements establishing the existence and
    maintenance of a cover register and/or the
    transfer of the cover assets to a legally remote
    vehicle (an SPV) to ensure investors' access
    to the cover assets.
    SME Small and Medium (sized) Enterprises
    Soft bullet See "Bullet structures"
    Solvency II Directive 2009/138/EC on the taking-up and
    pursuit of the business of Insurance and
    Reinsurance
    117
    Special public supervision A requirement in UCITS article 52 (4)
    demanding for the issuer of the covered
    bonds to be "subject by law to special public
    supervision designed to protect bond-
    holders". The demands for the supervision are
    not further defined in UCITS.
    Substitute cover assets Assets held in addition to the primary assets
    in the cover pool, typically represented by
    derivatives and other assets held for liquidity
    purposes.
    UCITS Directive 2009/65/EC on the coordination of
    laws, regulations and administrative
    provisions relating to undertakings for
    collective investment in transferable
    securities